3,278
Views
7
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Infrastructural power: discretion and the dynamics of infrastructure in action

Pages 644-661 | Received 13 Jun 2020, Accepted 30 Mar 2021, Published online: 20 May 2021

ABSTRACT

This article analyses how a pair of nineteenth century commodity exchanges—in Chicago and New Orleans—shaped the sociotechnical infrastructures underlying two key types of market information—price quotations and crop statistics. Specifically, the paper investigates why these exchanges saw divergent outcomes, each successfully developing one information infrastructure but not the other. Prior scholarship has understood infrastructural development as the result of idiosyncratic, social structural alignments in actors’ resources and desires. This paper, by contrast, examines how such structural elements interacted with practical resources available to exchanges based on their roles within infrastructures. Findings demonstrate that the exchanges gained influence in proportion to their discretion over an infrastructure's everyday operations and the market routines these enabled. This ‘infrastructural power', or lack thereof, interacted with social structural resources in two distinct forms— ‘feedback’ in New Orleans and ‘sacrifice’ in Chicago—providing or denying each exchange the ability to shape infrastructures to its advantage. These findings suggest that analysts should pay closer attention to market dynamics as they relate to ‘infrastructure in action’.

Introduction

In 1871, the Impressionist painter Edgar Degas traveled from France to visit his uncle, a cotton broker in New Orleans. Degas’s depiction of his uncle’s workplace, A Cotton Office in New Orleans (1873), shows business proceeding at the languid pace of a humid Louisiana afternoon. There is a decided lack of urgency amongst the men in the scene. Only a few appear to be working, inspecting sample cotton, or reviewing an account book. The others seem to be onlookers, visitors, or loafers. In fact, the two central figures of the painting are each seated alone, quite contentedly unengaged in business—one slouches in his chair, smoking, reading the newspaper, while the other unhurriedly cleans his glasses.

Unknowingly, Degas captured in his image the last gasp of this informal, slow-paced version of the cotton trade and agricultural markets more generally. In the coming years, the world’s markets in cotton, wheat, soybeans, corn, and other agricultural goods would be reconfigured within a far more energetic and demanding mode of organization: the commodity exchange (Markham Citation2002). Exchanges were voluntary associations that brought together actors from across a city’s agricultural trade—merchants, brokers, warehousemen, manufacturers, shipping agents, insurance agents—for the purposes of growing and regulating their business. Exchanges set rules of competition and cooperation, settled members’ disputes via private arbitration, and promoted uniformity in trade practices such as delivery, giving of margins, and establishing commission or storage rates. Many also established commodity-grading standards, facilitating global trading in cash markets, as well as the growth of speculative ‘futures’ markets. But beyond fostering cooperation among a city’s traders, possibly the most significant effect of the shift to exchange-based markets was the geographic consolidation of economic information (Markham Citation1987). Exchanges provided a central location for information exchange both informally through gossip and chatter as well as through official posting of information gathered using the pooled resources of its members. No longer would trading occur scattered across the offices, street corners, and saloons of a city, nor would information be passed primarily along private channels. Offices like those depicted by Degas—dislocated from other traders and the latest information—were pushed to the periphery. The real market was to be found on the exchange.

This article studies one facet of that historical shift, tracing the efforts of two major American commodity exchanges—the Chicago Board of Trade (CBOT) and New Orleans Cotton Exchange (NOCE)—to provide valuable information to their members in the decades after the Civil War. Particularly, it analyses these exchanges’ contrasting successes and failures in securing two key types of information: price quotations and crop statistics. Quotations—the prices at which agricultural commodities and futures contracts were bought and sold on other exchanges—offered a rapidly-changing view of the market. This information was becoming increasingly important. Globalization, standardization of goods, and increased speculative trading served to tightly link commodity markets the world over, making price quotations from hundreds or even thousands of miles away critical signals for traders. Crop statistics provided information about the growth, movement, and consumption of agricultural goods. In contrast to price quotations, they arrived weekly or monthly, rather than in minutes or seconds. While quotations offered a glimpse at how other traders were interpreting the market, statistics provided material for traders to make their own judgments on where prices were headed. The CBOT and NOCE diverged in their provision of each type of information to their members. Price quotations were successfully gathered and widely distributed to members of the CBOT, while on the NOCE they were disseminated unevenly and unpredictably. Conversely, the NOCE provided a vast amount of coordinated statistical information, which was used widely by its members, while statistics on the CBOT remained scattershot and unreliable. This informational divergence contributed to the production of markets and traders with distinct characters and orientations (Pinzur Citation2016).

Why did the exchanges diverge so significantly in the quality of information they offered their members? Answering this question requires recognizing that providing this information was not simply a technical challenge. It necessitated the integration of a range of material technologies (e.g. telegraphic wires and terminals, crop reporting forms), organizational protocols (e.g. rules for collecting, disseminating, and displaying information), state regulations (e.g. regarding who could access what information and for what purposes), and cultural understandings (e.g. what makes a particular type of information valuable, what makes a market fair) into operative wholes. The day-to-day relations and practices of the actors involved (e.g. exchanges, telegraph companies, statisticians, regulators, farmers) had to be coordinated smoothly enough so that exchange members could count upon the presence and worth of the information provided. Following STS scholars, we can refer to these integrated relations and coordinated practices across technical, organizational, and social components as ‘information infrastructures’ (Bowker Citation2010, Campbell-Verduyn et al. Citation2019).

Given this, our question is better stated as: Why did the information infrastructures on the CBOT and NOCE diverge so significantly? Previous research has demonstrated that infrastructures are shaped by broad political, economic, cultural, and organizational factors (Edwards Citation2003, Edwards Citation2009, MacKenzie Citation2018a). Actors apply social structural resources possessed by virtue of their positions within overlapping fields (Fligstein Citation2002, Bourdieu Citation2005, Fourcade Citation2007) hoping to shape an infrastructure's features to their own benefit. Those with structural advantages have a greater chance to impact the final result (Pardo-Guerra Citation2015, MacKenzie Citation2017). The current article builds on this research by claiming that actors’ discretion over their own practical contributions to the operation of an infrastructure constitutes an additional, discrete source of ‘infrastructural power’ (Braun Citation2020). Insofar as these actors' contributions are necessary for the smooth functioning of an infrastructure, their ability to enable or disrupt others' everyday routines constitutes a practical form of influence (Law Citation1990). While social structural power shapes an infrastructure’s features from without, infrastructural power allows contestation from within.

This article argues that the interaction of social structural and infrastructural resources shaped information infrastructures on the CBOT and NOCE. On the NOCE, initial social structural strengths and weaknesses were amplified through the exercise of infrastructural power in a process I call ‘feedback’. On one hand, the NOCE leveraged its organizational and cultural stature to shape a crop statistic infrastructure in which it became technically indispensable to the routines of traders; on the other, the Exchange's economic and political weaknesses within the price quotation infrastructure led directly to a lack of discretion in everyday action and an inability to contest prejudicial elements. By contrast, the CBOT began negotiations over both price quotation and crop statistic infrastructures with sizeable organizational and economic resources. It successfully combined these resources with its own infrastructural power to force beneficial changes to the price quotation infrastructure. In the process, however, it assumed positions within the cultural and legal environment such that building a viable crop statistic infrastructure became far more difficult. This process, which I label ‘sacrifice’, was key to the infrastructural divergence on the CBOT.

The article proceeds in six parts. The next section reviews the main approaches to market infrastructures in order to highlight the distinctiveness of the concept of infrastructural power and the analysis of infrastructure in action. I then introduce the two exchanges and describe the materially-mediated relations and practices involved in price quotation and crop statistic infrastructures. The fourth section presents findings demonstrating the ongoing, intertwined exercise of infrastructural and social structural power as each exchange sought to shape and re-shape their information infrastructures. Section five discusses implications of these findings, including the need for increased theoretical attention to the dynamics of infrastructure in action across multiple infrastructures. Finally, section six briefly restates the value of the research for scholarship on market infrastructures.

Politics and power in infrastructure

This article conceptualizes price quotations and crop statistics as products of infrastructures— ‘collections of technological devices, standards, classifications, protocols and material arrangements’ that support action locally while enabling global coordination (Pardo-Guerra Citation2015, p. 6). Infrastructures draw together a wide range of actors, devices, and practices across technical, organizational, and social environments into (more or less cohesively) attuned wholes that transparently underlie higher-order behaviors (Edwards Citation2003, Bowker Citation2010). Infrastructures, in addition to providing information, enable market activities such as price setting (Muniesa Citation2007), delivery (Pinzur Citation2016), settlement (Jeffs Citation2008, Krarup Citation2019), clearing (Millo Citation2005), order matching (Pardo-Guerra Citation2015), risk assessment (Poon Citation2009), and payment processing (Guseva and Rona-Tas Citation2014). Providing market infrastructures has become an increasingly important component of global exchanges’ business practices (Petry Citation2020).

Infrastructures remain below the visible surface of transactions, yet produce ‘world-ordering arrangements’ (Carse Citation2012, p. 543) with wide-ranging—and potentially unequal—consequences (Jeffs Citation2008, Lampland and Star Citation2009). As a result, their construction is often marked by contestation among multiple stakeholders. Technical components may be contested by engineers holding contrasting goals for a system (Pardo-Guerra Citation2019, Citation2015) or users seeking a material advantage over competitors (MacKenzie Citation2012, MacKenzie Citation2018b); managers and workers clash over infrastructures with an eye toward their impact on work routines and cultures (Bowker and Star Citation2000, Muniesa Citation2007); legislators and regulatory agencies fight to define infrastructures and their legitimate forms in ways that appease vested interests or broaden their own ambit (Millo Citation2007, MacKenzie Citation2018a). In short, market infrastructures are not neutral, efficient outcomes, but contested reflections of the perspectives and desires of those with the power to shape them.

Actors involved in these struggles to shape infrastructures draw upon whatever organizational, cultural, economic, political, or material resources they can access from their position within multiple, overlapping fields (Fligstein Citation2002, Bourdieu Citation2005, Fourcade Citation2007). Meso- and macro-level elites utilize their political and economic power to ensure infrastructural advantages, exemplified in the ability of financial firms and lobbyists to mold market infrastructures (Mirowski and Nik-Khah Citation2007, Erturk Citation2013, Hardin and Rottinghaus Citation2015). Regulators, rating agencies, and economists draw upon their expert status to assert legitimate domain over infrastructural issues (Guala Citation2001, Millo Citation2007, MacKenzie Citation2018a). Micro-level actors, though often unable to intervene in the initial creation of an infrastructure, creatively repurpose the new material and cultural resources it produces in service of local goals, preferences, and commitments (MacKenzie Citation2003, Erturk et al. Citation2013, MacKenzie and Pardo-Guerra Citation2014, MacKenzie and Spears Citation2014). Coming full circle, this creativity at the micro level can lead to new, unforeseen connections among an infrastructure’s components, forming ‘long chains’ (Campbell-Verduyn et al. Citation2019) that become critical sites for meso- and macro-level intervention (MacKenzie Citation2017).

This work, which broadly represents a ‘material political economy' (MacKenzie 2017) approach, shows how the social environment across multiple scales and fields impacts infrastructures. Yet, I argue that this literature's attention to instances where social structure and infrastructure come together has meant overlooking their ongoing connection via mundane, infrastructural relations and practices. These everyday elements are, though, central to STS approaches to infrastructure (Bowker Citation1994, Star and Ruhleder Citation1996). The analytical strategy of ‘infrastructural inversion' (Bowker Citation1994) demonstrates that any infrastructure that remains invisible, automatic, and taken for granted by one group must remain a highly visible, complex, source of constant engagement for another. Scholars must reckon with the dynamics produced in this ‘situated practical work of developing and using’ an infrastructure (Karasti et al. Citation2016, p. 4, emphasis added). Such an analysis is needed particularly because everyday, infrastructural work is itself a contingent, distributed process: not only is infrastructure constantly made, ‘but at the same time, it is - as a resistant and lively socio-material assemblage - part of this making process’ (Silvast and Virtanen Citation2019, p. 464, emphasis added). The dynamics of an ‘infrastructure in action’ will vary according to the ongoing sociotechnical relations it entails and have consequences for its connection to the broader social structural environment.

One valuable concept with which to consider these everyday relations is that of ‘infrastructural power' (Braun Citation2020). Actors hold infrastructural power insofar as they have discretion to engage in or withdraw from labour that is critical to the functioning of an infrastructure itself (Law Citation1990). Braun (Citation2020), for instance, demonstrates how financial actors' infrastructurally critical positions as conduits for central banks’ monetary policies afford them sizeable influence. Policymakers become loath to restrict the financial sector due to their expectation that this ‘would blunt their own policy instruments and thus diminish their control over the economy’ (Braun Citation2020, p. 400). In a similar vein, Mitchell (Citation2013) demonstrates that nineteenth century British coal miners' ability to withhold the labour needed to produce the nation's energy gave them an infrastructural power that they successfully converted into political influence. Finally, Besky's (Citation2016) analysis of the Indian tea market shows how brokers leveraged their centrality to the market's ‘communicative infrastructure’ to resist efforts at financialization. In these situations, infrastructures were not only momentary subjects of contestation, but also ongoing means of exerting power through discretion over indispensable, everyday labour. (Features of structural and infrastructural power are summarized in .)

Table 1. Features of social structural and infrastructural power.

This article's main theoretical goal is to untangle the distinct ways in which infrastructural and social structural power come together to shape market infrastructures. The development and use of price quotation and crop statistic infrastructures on New Orleans and Chicago's post-bellum exchanges provide contrasting cases for analysis.

Cases & methods

The Chicago Board of Trade (CBOT) and New Orleans Cotton Exchange (NOCE) were leading representatives of the new commodity exchanges gaining prominence in the latter half of the nineteenth century. The CBOT was established in 1848 to help bring order to Chicago’s rapidly growing agricultural marketing business (Taylor Citation1917). After the Civil War, the Board was home to several of the world’s largest agricultural markets, making it a critical player in global trade, a position it would retain well into the twentieth century (Cronon Citation1992). The NOCE was established in 1871 primarily as a means to revive New Orleans’s flagging spot trade in cotton, which had declined precipitously from its antebellum peak (Bouilly Citation1975). While it was unable to fully reverse changes wrought by the growth of railroad transport and loss of river-based commerce (Shannon Citation1945, Woodman Citation1963, Rothstein Citation1966), the Exchange did re-establish New Orleans’s position as the country’s premier market for spot cotton sales domestically and internationally, as well as introduce a sizeable futures market (Ellis Citation1973, Bouilly Citation1975). Both exchanges during this period operated under comparable legal and regulatory systems (Pinzur Citation2016).

Both exchanges sought to provide pertinent information on the state of world markets as a service to their members. The two types of information analysed in this article—price quotations and crop statistics—were particularly important. But gathering these required infrastructures composed of distinct actors, relations, materials, and practices.

Quotations—the prices at which commodities and futures were bought and sold on other markets—relied upon telegraphic transmission as their main technological component. Exchanges most commonly judged this technology by its ability to deliver speedy, reliable service. Delays of even a minute could prove costly to exchange members who would be open to predation from those with faster, private connections. Organizationally, the day-to-day operation of the infrastructure was negotiated between individual exchanges and the telegraph companies that served them. Each exchange would contract with a telegraph company both to send out quotations of sales from their own market and bring in the same from other exchanges. The NOCE and CBOT each secured their quotations through Western Union. In reality, they had little choice in the matter. During the 1860s and 1870s, Western Union took full advantage of weak anti-trust enforcement in the telegraph industry, acquiring major competitors and assuming control of a commanding share of the market. With the public’s desire for a state-owned telegraph service dwindling Western Union wielded their near-monopoly power mercilessly, raising prices, ignoring complaints, and delaying technical upgrades (Chandler Citation1977, John Citation2010).

The infrastructure required to produce and disseminate crop reports—statistics about the growth, movement, and consumption of agricultural goods—was quite different. The core challenge was not technological, but organizational. A crop statistic infrastructure required gathering data from myriad, widely-dispersed individuals and organizations—farmers, processors, railroad agents, shippers—as well as compiling this dispersed data at a ‘center of calculation’ (Latour Citation1988). Creating and maintaining crop reports required collaboration between informants with local knowledge, statisticians with mathematical expertise, and a publishing organization with regional, if not national, reach. State and federal governments attempted to organize this infrastructure beginning in the 1860s, but the statistics they produced were notoriously inaccurate (Pietruska Citation2012). If exchanges wanted more useful crop statistics, they would need to secure them through private infrastructures.

This article asks how the CBOT and NOCE fit into these networks of actors, practices, and relations, what sorts of infrastructural and social structural power they exerted from these positions, and how the interaction of these contributed to the observed divergence in information they brought to their members. The answer draws on multiple sources of data: the CBOT and NOCE archives, which contained annual reports, organizational records, published books and pamphlets, correspondence and meeting minutes, as well as relevant committee records; newspaper data from the Chicago Tribune and New Orleans Daily-Picayune; and secondary sources on the histories of each exchange. Materials range from the earliest sustained debates over these infrastructures, in the 1870s, up until 1914 when the US government temporarily assumed control of agricultural marketing in response to the destabilizing effects of World War I. Data were analysed using an inductively-formed, recursively-refined set of thematic codes.

As noted previously, the goal of the article is to detail the combined influence of infrastructural and social structural power in producing divergent informational outcomes on the two exchanges. The findings that follow reveal two different modes of interaction, which I label ‘feedback' and ‘sacrifice.' In a situation of feedback—seen on the NOCE—actors' initial positions of strength or weakness in one area (social structural or infrastructural) were subsequently amplified in the other. In the situation of sacrifice—seen on the CBOT—efforts to align infrastructural and social structural power in one infrastructure undermined like efforts in the other. These dynamics demonstrate the multi-faceted, bi-directional relation between infrastructural and social structural power, as well as the complex interactions between infrastructural context and practice. To highlight the cases' contrasts, the findings are organized by infrastructure, reviewing first both exchanges' efforts to provide price quotations, then their work on crop statistics. The intra-exchange dynamics of ‘feedback' on the NOCE and ‘sacrifice' on the CBOT are noted when appropriate, to be explicated at length in the article’s discussion section.

Price quotations

Chicago

In 1848, the introduction of the telegraph served as a catalyst for Chicago’s evolution into the country’s grain marketing hub. But by the 1880s, the Board had developed entrenched conflicts over the day-to-day operation of the telegraph with service provider Western Union. Two aspects were critical. First, the CBOT, like most other exchanges, wanted faster service and lower rates. The Board’s motives were purely economic: faster provisioning of quotations made it a more attractive trading venue, while lower prices meant more money for the association to use elsewhere (Taylor Citation1917, see also, Preda Citation2006, on connection to ticker tape). The second, more significant, desired change was not (primarily) economic in origin, but political. From the time of its founding, the Board had been accused of promoting gambling under the guise of trade, particularly via speculation on its agricultural futures markets (Cronon Citation1992, de Goede Citation2005). Rebutting these claims and defending the legitimacy of its practices against public opprobrium were ongoing efforts (Lurie Citation1979). This work became more difficult beginning in the late 1880s thanks to the growing presence of ‘bucket shops’—local gambling shops where patrons could, for a small fee, place bets on the fluctuations of the CBOT’s price quotations (Fabian Citation1999, Hochfelder Citation2006). These quotations were supplied to the shops directly by Western Union and other telegraph operators. The increase in bucket shop activities reinforced the public's association of the Board with gambling and reinvigorated state and federal efforts to regulate trading (Lurie Citation1979). To quash this harmful association with gambling, the CBOT asked Western Union to cease disseminating their price quotations to bucket shops. But Western Union fought hard against any changes in service. The outcome of this clash would depend on which organization could muster the structural and infrastructural resources necessary to shape the price quotation infrastructure over the coming decades.

The CBOT first attempted to exert control over the price quotation infrastructure by creating their own alternative telegraph networks. In 1880, several CBOT members joined with a group of Milwaukee businessmen to form a telegraph company that directly linked the grain exchanges in both cities, circumventing Western Union’s wires (“CitationCheap Telegraphing Pays”). The company was a success. The cost of constructing the line was recouped within two years of operation and the increased competition drove down Western Union’s prices on that section by 80% in just a few years (“CitationNew Line of Telegraph”). In 1883, seeking to replicate this success, the CBOT attempted to construct and operate a direct telegraphic connection with the Merchants’ Exchange in St. Louis. But Western Union, having learned their lesson in Milwaukee, squashed the project by pressuring local landowners to engage the Board in a tangle of litigation and, for good measure, sending armed gangs to tear down recently erected poles and segments of wire (“CitationJudge Wall Hearing the Case of the Board of Trade vs. Western Union at East St. Louis”). After more than two years of costly struggle against this obstruction, the CBOT called off the project. The experience soured the Board on the circumvention strategy more broadly, leading them to withdraw from a contemporaneous plan to build an independent telegraph line on the critically important Chicago-New York route. It simply did not have the resources to fend off the legal, economic, and political challenges that Western Union was sure to mount in response.Footnote1

Lacking the resources to circumvent Western Union entirely, the CBOT then sought to use its infrastructural power to increase pressure on the company. Key to their strategy was the fact that the price quotation infrastructure operated through inter-dependency: exchanges needed telegraphic delivery of information on the status of other world markets, but telegraph companies could only meet this need if exchanges supplied them with quotations. CBOT directors calculated that withholding their own quotations would so disturb trading on other exchanges and hurt Western Union’s income that the company would be forced to negotiate on issues of infrastructure. So, in 1890, the CBOT took the drastic step of removing itself from the price quotation infrastructure altogether, expelling all telegraph operators from the floor of the exchange in an effort to force Western Union to the bargaining table.

The effort backfired. Many CBOT brokers lost clients, who chose to execute their trades on exchanges that still received public quotations.Footnote2 Members who had grown reliant on public provision of price quotations left the Board to trade in places that still had a telegraphic connection—ironically, often the very bucket shops the policy was meant to eliminate.Footnote3 Furthermore, quotations were regularly smuggled off the exchange floor and disseminated around the country (Taylor Citation1917). As one angry Board member pointed out more than a year into the policy: ‘It is well known that in New York, in Minneapolis, in St. Louis, in Chicago, any man who wishes to pay $1.00 a week can get every shade of quotation that is made on the Board of Trade.’Footnote4 Faced with the failure to achieve any pressure through its actions, the Board rescinded the policy the very next year.

By the end of the century, having failed to materially circumvent or overpower Western Union, the CBOT redoubled its efforts to establish control over the price infrastructure through legal means (Lurie Citation1979). As it happened, the pivotal case came in February 1900 when a prominent bucket shop, the Christie-Street Commission Company, filed an injunction against the Board to prevent any cessation of its market quotations. In arguing the case, the Board’s lawyers drew on the legally and culturally significant distinction between productive contracts and destructive wagers (Hochfelder Citation2006, Levy Citation2006). Price quotations on the Board, they argued, served legitimate commercial purposes, while in bucket shops they were purely fodder for illegal gambling (Sager Citation1908).Footnote5 In June 1900, reversing the trend of previous trials, the Illinois Supreme Court affirmed these claims, ruling that the Board could legally withhold its quotations from bucket shops.

The day after the decision was handed down, the Board contacted Western Union, demanding that it cease supplying quotations to bucket shops. But Western Union made no immediate response to either the court’s ruling or the CBOT’s demand. Believing in the power of its position, it appealed the case to the U.S. Supreme Court and continued supplying quotations to bucket shops as usual (Lurie Citation1979, de Goede Citation2005). The state court’s decision did, however, alter the institutional environment enough that the CBOT could re-adopt older, infrastructural power-based tactics, which now hit with increased force. The first such tactic was withholding price quotations, albeit more adroitly than previously. Aware now of their own reliance on the telegraph, the CBOT did not disconnect themselves from the infrastructure entirely, but simply cut back on the frequency with which Western Union could gather quotations from the floor (“CitationPlan Lines For Their Own Use”). This struck the right balance, hurting Western Union and the exchanges that were its customers more than it hurt CBOT members. The second tactic was to resurrect the old, discarded plan to circumvent Western Union on the key Chicago-New York route by building an independent telegraph line with the New York Produce Exchange. Though it had dismissed the possibility two decades prior, the CBOT now projected that wires could be up and running in just over four years (“CitationVote For a New Telegraph Line,” “CitationEnters Telegraphic Field”). Western Union, already losing money from the slowdown in quotations, confronting the possibility of further pro-CBOT court rulings, and now facing the specter of a serious competitor for telegraphic traffic, recognized that it had lost control over the price quotation infrastructure. In March 1901—four years before the Christie case was finally settled by the U.S. Supreme Court—it agreed not only to limit dissemination of quotations to Board-approved recipients,Footnote6 but also to increase its payment for collecting CBOT quotations from $6,000 to $30,000 per year (“CitationQuotation War May Be Ended,” “CitationQuotation War to Continue”).Footnote7

New Orleans

In New Orleans, the NOCE did not face the problem of bucket shops to anywhere near the same degree as the CBOT.Footnote8 It did, however, face significant technological challenges posed by the South’s degraded, post-war telegraphic infrastructure (John Citation2010). At the onset of the Civil War, Union forces had cut many telegraph lines extending from north to south across the Mason-Dixon line. During the war much telegraphic property was destroyed. Companies serving the South barely had enough business to stay afloat, let alone to repair damaged lines or expand coverage. After the war, the American Telegraph Company, which operated the main route to the north, planned to invest half a million dollars repairing its lines. The plans were scrapped, however, in 1866, when the company was absorbed by Western Union (Thompson Citation1947). At the founding of the Exchange five years later, little had been done to rebuild or expand southern lines (John Citation2010).

The main problem facing the Exchange was speed. The delivery of quotations was simply too slow. Delays were particularly pronounced at busy times such as the opening of the market or periods of large price fluctuations—the precise moments when traders most needed timely updates.Footnote9 The slow service on the Exchange’s public wire led to a persistent problem with ‘beats,’ i.e. instances where price quotations reached commission houses along private wires faster than the same information came to the Exchange over public lines.Footnote10 As a result of this time differential, members associated with private houses had a chance to act on information before it became common knowledge. The slow telegraphic connection also deprived the NOCE of business from merchants looking to place orders in the futures market. Even Southern merchants who wished to patronize a Southern exchange simply could not take on the risk entailed by the slow telegraph connection and sent their business to New York instead.Footnote11 For these reasons, increasing the speed at which price quotations moved through its market was at the forefront of the NOCE’s concerns.

But the NOCE, unlike the CBOT, had few social structural resources it could marshal to alter the state of the quotation infrastructure. It lacked the capital to circumvent Western Union, as a brief, failed exploration of a direct line to New York made clear.Footnote12 Even more significantly, the NOCE had no natural allies who would also benefit from altering the telegraphic infrastructure. Critical in this regard was the Exchange’s position as the second-largest American cotton futures market, behind the New York Cotton Exchange (NYCE). This small difference in trading volume led to a spiraling loss of influence. Since prices on global markets were becoming more closely linked—itself a consequence of telegraphic infrastructures—European markets could increasingly take the price in New York to represent the US market as a whole. The investment effects of the NYCE’s premier position further hastened the NOCE’s irrelevance: New York attracted more capital, which made its markets more liquid, which made them even more attractive trading sites (Markham Citation1987). In its powerlessness, the NOCE’s only recourse for poor service was haranguing Western Union for improvements, a strategy that, predictably, saw little success. Writing in 1908, after two decades of pleas had fallen on deaf ears, the NOCE’s Committee on Information and Statistics admitted that its arguments had, ‘been gone over so often with the telegraph officials with no appreciable result, that [it was] at loss what further to do.’Footnote13

Its secondary position meant that the NOCE also was at a disadvantage in negotiations over the organizational protocols governing the day-to-day operation of the price quotation infrastructure. One such protocol was the NYCE’s so-called ‘ten-minute rule.’ This rule allowed a member to withhold reporting a trade in futures to the Exchange for ten minutes. During this time, they could privately wire news of the trade to their partners in New Orleans, who would have the jump on members relying on the public wire.Footnote14 A second prejudicial arrangement was that the NYCE publicly transmitted to the NOCE only quotations of finalized sales, while commission houses often privately received news not just of sales, but also of offers and bids. This let them suss out market trends early. A trader who relied on the public wire in New Orleans, gave the following example:

Some days since [a futures contract for delivery in] a certain month was quoted at 10:30 AM in New York, 11 cents; by 10:31, it was offered at 10.99; then at ‘98, ‘97, ‘96, and ‘95 successively; but because there were no sales we did not get a quotation until 10:33, when a transaction was made at 10.95. The successive offers of ‘99 to ‘95 were known through private resources, but the Exchange was without information because it had to wait until an actual sale.Footnote15

Both rules put NOCE traders taking quotations from the public wire at a disadvantage. New York’s economic advantage allowed them to slow-pedal their response to the Exchange’s complaints for years. In this way, the NOCE’s disadvantages at the field level extended to, and were reinforced in, the everyday relations and practices of the infrastructure in action.

These cases demonstrate the interaction of structural and infrastructural power in the CBOT and NOCE’s efforts to reshape price quotation infrastructures. The history on the CBOT illustrates a back-and-forth movement between the two forms. Following initial success using organizational resources to create its own telegraphic line, the CBOT encountered the limits of its structural power in the face of Western Union’s superior legal and economic resources. While its initial turn to infrastructural power—removing the telegraph from the floor of the exchange—was a failure, the CBOT eventually skillfully combined its discretion within the operation of the price quotation infrastructure with a more favourable legal landscape. From its initial, middling levels of both structural and infrastructural power, the CBOT effectively leveraged incremental gains in one with increased pressure in the other. By contrast, the NOCE’s structural and infrastructural weaknesses exacerbated one another. Its economic and organizational importance to Western Union and other exchanges was weakened by its secondary position vis-à-vis New York, the largest and best-connected cotton market, which became the American representative. This disadvantaged structural position was reinforced infrastructurally by Western Union’s intransigence and New York’s prejudicial rules. In total, these left the NOCE with few tools to fight against further depredations, let alone to seek improvements in the day-to-day operation of the price quotation infrastructure.

However, as the next sections will show, the combination of structural and infrastructural power regarding crop statistic infrastructures led to precisely opposite outcomes.

Crop statistics

New Orleans

Prior to the founding of the NOCE in 1871, New Orleans tradesmen made no effort to produce their own statistics on the growth and movement of the cotton crop. Instead, they relied on piecemeal information from travelers, statistical bulletins from the federal government, and private crop reports from companies based in New York and Liverpool (Sherman Citation1934). Prior to the War, with business booming and New Orleans the leading American cotton port, this arrangement met traders’ needs. But following the War, the habit of ‘patiently waiting for [others] to tell [them] what they knew’ about the state of cotton was deemed to be both insulting and bad business (Frost Citation1926, np). As a business strategy, it kept New Orleans ‘in leading strings,’ further cementing its status as subordinate to New York.Footnote16 Additionally, the NOCE feared that these reports, coming from markets largely representing manufacturers’ interests, might be manipulated so as to depress cotton prices (Bouilly Citation1976). Finally, after the experiences of the Civil War, occupation by Union forces, and Reconstruction, the indignity of relying on northern sources for information about the South’s staple crop increasingly grated on traders’ sense of pride.Footnote17 In response to this dissatisfaction, the NOCE’s young secretary, Henry Hester, set out from the earliest days of the Exchange to construct a network for gathering statistics on the growth and movement of the U.S. cotton crop.Footnote18 His goal, in his own words, was to ‘make the South the authority for facts concerning the growth and distribution of its great staple, cotton’ (Frost Citation1926, np).

This crop statistic infrastructure required procedures for gathering, standardizing, and commensurating information. Compared to the work of a telegraph company, it required little capital, but extensive social coordination. In this regard, the extant organizational connections and cultural solidarity among Southern businessmen helped the NOCE. Hester tapped knowledgeable and well-respected local middlemen known as ‘factors’ to serve as intermediaries in the earliest stages of the infrastructure’s development (Ellis Citation1973). As the infrastructure grew to be national in scope, the NOCE drew upon the coordination already present among exchanges, mills, cotton dealers, and planters as part of the longstanding, shared system for classifying and judging the quality of cotton (Boyle Citation1934). While not designed to gather statistics, this network offered a platform from which the statistical infrastructure grew.Footnote19 Coordination was aided further by the efforts of the National Cotton Exchange (NCE), which, in 1874, joined Hester’s statistical project, organizing expanded data collection through its member exchanges.Footnote20 Over the next few years, this network with Hester in charge grew steadily and implemented a uniform questionnaire for use in obtaining monthly crop information.Footnote21

The developments were well-received among members. After its first full year, the NOCE’s Committee on Information and Statistics reported that the system had seen ‘a fair degree of success,’Footnote22 and the following year’s report noted ‘the increased favor with which the system is received both here and elsewhere.’Footnote23 By the system’s third year, the crop reports had become central to the everyday routines of traders, whose ‘thirst for information heretofore considered valueless [was] steadily increasing,’ feeding a growing consensus ‘in favor of obtaining and spreading abroad valuable facts’ regarding the growth and movement of cotton. Footnote24

This incorporation of crop statistics into actors’ everyday routines was critical for sustaining Hester’s project through a subsequent, difficult period. Though the crop reporting system was growing, by the end of the decade, data was becoming increasingly inaccurate. One problem was that even with the newly standardized questionnaires correspondents still interpreted questions differently. This problem was compounded by the National Exchange’s requirement that member exchanges merely compile responses as received, exercising no discretion over the acceptance or rejection of answers.Footnote25 In addition to commensurability problems, the method of measuring the size of the annual crop by estimating changes year over year meant that inaccuracies multiplied over time. The further it got from 1870—the year of the latest decennial census—the less accurate the estimates became.Footnote26 By 1879, even with data from an unprecedented number of respondents, the NOCE claimed that it could not make any ‘predictions’ about the cotton crop but only present ‘an intelligent general view of the crop prospects.’Footnote27 In 1882, citing persistent inaccuracies, the NCE ceased compiling monthly reports of crop and acreage.Footnote28 The NOCE immediately objected. Citing the enthusiastic incorporation of statistics into previous years’ trading routines, they argued that the monthly crop and acreage reports ‘were of too much importance to be omitted.’Footnote29 Hester and others argued that the solution to current problems was not to abandon, but to improve, the statistical infrastructure. In 1884, after two years of advocacy from the NOCE, the board of the National Exchange was convinced and reinstated the reports.

The resumption of statistical reporting was simultaneously a vote of confidence in Secretary Hester, who assumed an even more central role. Reports were now sent directly to him rather than to committees of the local exchanges, so that he could supervise their compilation and publication. In 1887, after the NCE dissolved, Hester fully consolidated control of the statistical network and additionally incorporated the material resources of Cotton World, a weekly newspaper which he edited.Footnote30 The centralized control proved beneficial, as the infrastructure continued to grow without loss in accuracy. By 1890, Hester’s statistical infrastructure had grown so massive that his annual statement featured data from every delivery point, point of crossing on the Ohio, Mississippi and Potomac rivers, and all the mills in the South, without a single guess or estimate at any detail of the entire statement.Footnote31 NOCE crop reports once again ‘[bore] the stamp of recognized authority on both sides of the Atlantic.’Footnote32

With this renewed authority came an even more thoroughgoing incorporation of crop reports into the everyday routines of the market. Members called for ever greater quantities of information, claiming that ‘the trade wants news and facts’ and that ‘if we are to form opinions independent of other centres, it must be by being as well, if not better, posted.’Footnote33 During periods of market panic, Hester would be enlisted to publish sober quantitative assessments of the market, which would invariably urge traders to spurn rumours in favor of ‘looking facts squarely in the face and dealing with them accordingly’ (Hester, Citation1926, p.8). The plethora of statistical information provided on the Exchange was widely viewed as one of its leading features. In 1905, Exchange President Abraham Brittin claimed that the recent growth in membership was directly attributable to increased information-gathering efforts.Footnote34 The same year, the Futures Committee called for the Exchange ‘to enlarge the scope of information from every quarter where cotton is produced or manufactured.’Footnote35 Through steady development over three decades, Hester’s weekly statistical report became so integral to the routines of trade that no man in the cotton world would think of doing business without it, ‘any more than the captain of a ship would think of sailing from port without chart and compass and sextant’ (Frost Citation1926, np).

Chicago

As in New Orleans, traders in Chicago had no statistical infrastructure of their own at the founding of the Board. Their statistical reports similarly came from a hodge-podge of public and private sources, representing a wide range of values and opinions. Unlike, the NOCE, however, the Board never made a sustained effort to produce their own statistics or even coalesce around a single statistical source. This was not for lack of concern with the inadequacies of the status quo (Taylor Citation1917, Boyle Citation1934). Rather, contemporaneous organizational decisions and political factors made efforts to develop a statistical infrastructure complicated and risky.

Organizationally, the CBOT did not have a backdrop of inter-exchange coordination from which to build a statistics-gathering network. The CBOT’s leading wheat and corn markets, in contrast to cotton markets, had long resisted coordinating with other exchanges to produce uniform grading standards.Footnote36 As late as 1906, the CBOT was begging off efforts at standardization by both the US Department of Agriculture and the Grain Dealers National Association, arguing that national grading standards would be impracticable or hurt market prices.Footnote37 Further efforts at coordination, such as establishing standard minimum test weights for grades or widespread adoption of new grades, were also rejected with no explanation other than that they conflicted with current practice.Footnote38 The CBOT was not prepared to weaken its market-leading status for the sake of greater coordination, nor was any state agency or professional association in a position to impose such rules upon it.

The CBOT was also facing politically and legally resonant attacks regarding monopoly control that constrained their options in building a statistical infrastructure. These came from two sources. First, farmers argued that they had no choice but to send their grain to be sold on the CBOT, a necessity that undercut their bargaining power. These claims were of a piece with rural residents’ general suspicion that the Board’s actions were underhanded, parasitic, and benefited middlemen at the expense of farmers (Cronon Citation1992, Levy Citation2006). Amplified by populist politicians in state and federal legislatures, this claim of monopoly was a key justification—alongside the charge of gambling—in many of the over 200 bills introduced to Congress between 1880 and 1920 seeking to regulate commodity exchanges (Markham Citation1987). Second, charges of monopoly came from bucket shops and Western Union. Their claim, frequently made in the court battles discussed previously, was that the CBOT exerted monopoly control not over physical grain, but over information—i.e. price quotations—that ought to have been public. This claim was, in fact, affirmed by judges in several lower court rulings unfavorable to the Board (Lurie Citation1979).

In response to these dangerous charges of monopoly, the Board stressed its non-action and non-control as much as possible. Addressing the farmers’ charge, it claimed to be a purely neutral platform, rather than market participant—witness the very first section of a CBOT pamphlet, Things You Should Know About Chicago Board of Trade, titled, ‘The Exchange Itself Does No Business’ (emphasis added). (Rollins Citation1920) In response to charges of controlling information, the Board demonstrated its hands-off approach in relation to crop statistic infrastructures. Rather than produce its own information or even curate the information they gathered, the Board disseminated all reports ‘with absolutely no restriction … without prejudice or partiality,’ which they claimed to be ‘for the benefit of all concerned’ (Stone Citation1911). Even when the CBOT knew information was of dubious quality it chose to publish it and let members use their best judgment.Footnote39 The CBOT declined to join a 1912 effort from the Council of Grain Exchanges aimed at cutting out unreliable sources, stating that ‘there is good work with the bad, and it would be injudicious and fruitless to condemn the whole system … since there is a popular demand for such information.’Footnote40 Given the political and legal danger, and despite persistent entreaties from members, the CBOT made no effort to curate statistical information until 1918, at which point they took only the small step of certifying legitimate crop reporters.Footnote41

As a result of their inaction, the Board was flooded with conflicting crop reports from independent statisticians and market prognosticators that mixed slipshod data collection and analysis with a healthy dose of gut feeling and estimation. Unsurprisingly, these analyses varied greatly. The Chicago Tribune, as early as 1887, was denouncing the reports of these ‘private-wire oracles,’ saying that, ‘No two of them ever agree upon a prophecy—indeed they rarely agree upon statements of fact’ (“CitationPrivate New York Wires”). The Board’s lack of engagement with this infrastructure meant that statistical information was given little credence. Among members, common knowledge was that ‘the man who trades on statistics is on the highway to ruin’ (“CitationArticle 4 - No Title”).

The development of crop statistic infrastructures on the NOCE and CBOT were shaped by the interaction of social structural and infrastructural power. The NOCE began from a position of organizational strength, able to build upon a history of coordination via the National Exchange and use of shared grading standards. Its cultural stature as the center of the Southern cotton world and the significance of the statistical infrastructure as a means of achieving self-sufficiency further strengthened these organizational bonds and enrolled actors into the infrastructure. The value of the information produced and its widespread incorporation into calculative routines gave the NOCE infrastructural power to develop the system further, even in the face of inaccuracies. As reliance on the infrastructure grew, so too did the cultural authority of its central figure, Henry Hester. Conversely, the CBOT lacked any organizational ties upon which to build its statistical infrastructure, having long resisted coordination out of fear it would negatively impact its economic position. Further, charges of monopoly in legislatures and courts made the Board wary of any efforts at coordination or control. As a result, the statistical infrastructure remained a disjointed and unreliable source of information for traders.

Theoretical implications of infrastructural power

These findings demonstrate how the CBOT and NOCE gained influence over different information infrastructures via the interaction between social structural and infrastructural power. As prior research would suggest, each exchange drew on the economic, political, cultural, and organizational resources associated with their positions in multiple, overlapping fields to shape infrastructure to their benefit. But these resources became valuable insofar as exchanges could combine them with the ‘infrastructural power’ that came from their position within ongoing relations and practices that supported the routines of multiple actors. This combination happened via distinct dynamics—which I call ‘feeback’ and ‘sacrifice’— across the two cases.

On the NOCE, price quotation and crop statistic infrastructures developed via a process of ‘feedback,’ wherein an initially strong or weak structural position was reinforced over time through the exercise of infrastructural power—or vice versa. For example, in its price quotation infrastructure, the NOCE began with two challenges. Technically, they were unable to send and receive messages quickly; economically and organizationally, they were secondary to New York. Over time, these weaknesses grew deeper in relation to one another. The NOCE’s inability to establish or disrupt routines among a broad set of users through technical means (e.g. by building their own connections to the North) deprived them of any power in ensuing struggles over organizational features of the infrastructure (e.g. the protocols of information sharing). By contrast, the NOCE developed their crop statistic infrastructure from a position of extant organizational coordination and cultural value. These factors made the initial production of a statistical infrastructure simpler and more desirable. Over time, this infrastructure became central to routines of statistical calculation on the cotton exchanges. This widespread reliance then provided an independent resource which helped the NOCE push past early problems with the infrastructure. In the end, their technical competence was the basis for new levels of esteem within the cotton world.

On the CBOT, information infrastructures developed by a different process, which I label ‘sacrifice.’ As opposed to the NOCE, which began building their infrastructures from weak or strong positions, the CBOT developed both of their infrastructures from moderately powerful positions. On price quotations, it possessed some economic and organizational capacity to circumvent Western Union and its price quotations were highly valued by other exchanges; however, Western Union’s quasi-monopoly, the CBOT’s own members’ reliance on telegraphed price quotations, and the Board’s precarious legal position all worked against it. On crop statistics, the Board was weakened by a lack of prior coordination with other exchanges as well as accusations of monopoly control; yet the necessary infrastructural work was well within its capacity, with eager national associations available to be enrolled in the network, as well as state and private statistical reports that could have been harmonized with minimal capital. The CBOT’s divergent outcomes regarding these two infrastructures, then, were not simply continuations of initial conditions. Rather, the CBOT made decisions in pursuing control of its price quotation infrastructure that limited its ability to effectively contest the development of crop statistics. The Board, in its fight over the price quotation infrastructure, was forced to address charges that it controlled, altered, and monopolized information. It prevailed in these political and legal battles, in part, by commiting to principles of neutrality, non-action, and non-involvement in agricultural markets. But this commitment—and the costs that would come from breaking it—complicated the Board’s engagement with crop statistics. Rather than take any steps that could be viewed as intervention, the CBOT remained entirely hands-off, letting its statistical infrastructure languish for decades. In short, the CBOT sacrificed the ability to develop a statistical infrastructure in the process of building up control over price quotations.

This distinction points to certain critiques and areas for theoretical development. First, while a ‘feedback’ dynamic occurs over time within a single infrastructure, ‘sacrifice’ happens across the boundaries of multiple infrastructures Such dynamics across multiple infrastructures within an organization remain largely unstudied. Market infrastructures have generally been analysed in the singular: a grading infrastructure (Cronon Citation1992), a settlement infrastructure (Krarup Citation2019, Rella Citation2020), an execution infrastructure (MacKenzie Citation2017, Pardo-Guerra Citation2019). This article demonstrates that market infrastructures, particularly information infrastructures, can usefully be studied in the plural. Researchers should be alert to the new dynamics this multiplicity introduces to the production and maintenance of infrastructures. Beyond ‘sacrifice,’ one can easily imagine a technically-focused, path-dependent relationship (Mahoney Citation2000) where practical elements of one infrastructure demand particular features in other, linked infrastructures (e.g. the relation between commodity grading and contract settlement infrastructures (Pinzur Citation2016)). Beyond technical connections, one can imagine sets of infrastructures being discursively linked in relation to a particular organizational vision or goal (e.g. efficiency or equity), and thus rising or falling as one in relation to the status of that organizational discourse.

The second implication of these findings is that a focus on the ‘idiosyncratic’ alignment of interest and opportunity among actors in different fields (e.g. Kennedy Citation2017; MacKenzie Citation2018a) offers only a partial perspective of infrastructural change. This perspective suggests a primary process wherein social structural factors ‘congeal’ (Krippner Citation2001) in market infrastructures, determining their characteristics and capabilities. But the findings of this article show that infrastructures are not simply ‘[interwoven] with’ and given form by ‘episodes of cooperation and conflict’ (MacKenzie Citation2018a, p. 1680) at the field level. Additionally, they shape relations between conflicting parties and offer a distinct, interior pathway for forcing re-engagement with the form of an infrastructure. This suggests a more energetic role for infrastructural actors within a material political economy perspective. Scholars, in addition to describing how different fields meet at key moments to influence the development of market infrastructure, should investigate how infrastructural relations and practices cut across fields, extending into and altering social structure. Further research on this topic will promote a greater understanding of infrastructural change, particularly as it relates to dynamics of ‘infrastructure in action'.

Conclusion

This article has demonstrated the value of research on actors’ ongoing contributions to the web of relations and practices that comprises an infrastructure in action. To the degree that actors have discretion to enable or disrupt widespread routines they hold a form of infrastructural power, which can be used to force a renegotiation of the very infrastructure to which they contribute. In the cases of the CBOT and NOCE, the combination of their roles within price quotation and crop statistic infrastructures and their distinct social structural resources empowered both exchanges to mold one infrastructure, but not the other, an outcome with long-lasting consequences for their markets. In developing the concepts of ‘infrastructural power’ and ‘infrastructure in action,’ the article draws on the relational character of infrastructure to offer a new reply to the question of ‘who controls [a market] assemblage, and what socio-technical arrangements facilitate the exercise of that control’ (Erturk Citation2013, p. 339). The answer involves looking beyond the myriad, power-laden struggles that occur around an infrastructure toward the ways that power operates through an infrastructure.

While the cases analysed in this article are historical, the issues surrounding market infrastructure—particularly the politics of its construction, expansion, and alteration—are growing in their contemporary significance. Exchanges’ role as infrastructure providers, examined here in its infancy, has exploded in recent years, becoming a core business feature and source of power (Petry Citation2020). The trading of new instruments (e.g. cryptocurrencies) has depended on the construction of new infrastructures for recording and accounting for blockchain transactions (Hayes Citation2019, Rella Citation2020). Global financial integration is engaging states and private actors in challenging negotiations over cross-border infrastructures (Krarup Citation2019). The “Cambrian explosion” of fintech products battling for market share necessarily draws in the infrastructures needed to provide interoperability (Nelms Citation2018). The concepts and methods developed in this article’s historical analysis promise insight into the origins and mechanisms of power in these modern applications as well.

Acknowledgements

The author wishes to acknowledge Rebecca Elliott, Mikell Hyman, Manolis Kalaitzake, Juan Pablo Pardo-Guerra, Akos Rona-Tas, and members of the Sociology of Markets Workshop at the Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies for their thoughtful comments on early drafts, as well as Anna Muraco and Rebecca Sager at Loyola Marymount University for their professional and personal support during a critical period for this work. Thanks also to the editor and reviewers at Journal of Cultural Economy for their valuable feedback.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Additional information

Notes on contributors

David Pinzur

David Pinzur is an Assistant Professor of Sociology at the London School of Economics and Political Science. His research focuses on the sociology of finance, market infrastructures, and knowledge.

Notes

1 CBOT Board of Directors records, Box 7, Folder 10, Mar. 22, 1881; CBOT Board of Directors records, Box 9, Folder 34, Nov. 10, 1883

2 CBOT Organizational Records, Minutes of the Annual Meeting, Box 6, Folder 2, 1892

3 CBOT Organizational Records, Box 5, Folder 14, Nov. 9, 1891; CBOT Organizational Records, Minutes of the Annual Meeting, Box 6, Folder 2, 1892

4 CBOT Organizational Records, Box 5, Folder 14, Nov. 12, 1891

5 CBOT Organizational Records, Minutes of the Annual Meeting, Box 14, Folder 15, 1918

6 Each approved recipient of quotations had their own set of requirements to meet, which ensured that quotations were not then used for gambling purposes (CBOT Board of Directors records, Box 43, Folder 5, Oct. 23, 1900).

7 CBOT Organizational Records, Minutes of the Annual Meeting, Box 9, Folder 27, 1902

8 The first mention of bucket shops in NOCE Annual Reports comes in the 1903, with the addition of a “Committee on the Suppression of Bucket Shops,” whereas the CBOT formed a Special Committee on the issue back in 1882. The NOCE’s 1907 Annual Report notes that at the highest point there were 32 bucket shops in the state, compared with a high of 80 in the city of Chicago alone in 1895 (CBOT Annual Report, 1899). It is conceivable that Louisiana’s popular state lottery, which ran 1868–1893 may have provided an alternative for wagers from the general public.

9 NOCE Annual Report (AR), 1896; AR, 1911

10 NOCE Annual Report (AR), 1883, 1888, 1889, 1893, 1906, 1910

11 NOCE Volumes, #164, Jan. 12, 1920

12 NOCE Annual Report (AR), 1904

13 NOCE Annual Report (AR), 1908: 31

14 NOCE Annual Report (AR), 1896

15 NOCE Annual Report (AR), 1903: 31–32

16 NOCE Annual Report (AR), 1890: 32

17 NOCE Volumes, #127, January 5, 1875.

18 NOCE Photographs and other records, Box 72, Folder 8, May 24, 1871

19 NOCE Annual Reports, 1872

20 NOCE Annual Reports, 1874

21 NOCE Annual Reports, 1877

22 NOCE Annual Reports, 1872: 4

23 NOCE Annual Reports, 1873: 52

24 NOCE Annual Reports, 1874: 106

25 NOCE Annual Reports, 1881

26 NOCE Annual Reports, 1878

27 NOCE Annual Reports, 1879: 304

28 NOCE Annual Reports, 1882

29 NOCE Annual Reports, 1884: 24

30 NOCE Annual Reports, 1884; AR, 1885

31 NOCE Annual Reports, 1891

32 NOCE Annual Reports, 1890:31

33 NOCE Annual Reports, 1889: 26

34 NOCE Annual Reports, 1905: 11

35 NOCE Annual Reports, 1905: 37

36 CBOT Committee Records, Box 319, Folder 5, various dates, 1905–6

37 CBOT Committee Records, Box 319, Folder 4, Feb. 9, 1906;

38 CBOT Committee Records, Box 319, Folder 10, Mar. 19, 1907

39 CBOT Organizational Records, Minutes of the Annual Meeting (MAM), Box 14, Folder 7, 1915: 4.

40 CBOT Organizational Records, Box 13, Folder 10, Sept. 24, 1912

41 CBOT Board of Directors records, Box 84, Folder 37, Jun. 15, 1918

Bibliography

  • Article 4 – No Title, Chicago Tribune, Feb. 21, 1891, p.4
  • Besky, S., 2016. The future of price: communicative infrastructures and the financialization of Indian tea. Cultural Anthropology, 31, 4–29.
  • Bouilly, R.H., 1975. The development of American cotton exchanges, 1870-1916. Columbia, MO: University of Missouri–Columbia.
  • Bourdieu, P., 2005. The social structures of the economy. Cambridge: Polity.
  • Bowker, G., 1994. Information mythology and infrastructure. In: L Bud-Frierman, ed. Information acumen: The understanding and Use of knowledge in modern business. London: Routledge, 231–247.
  • Bowker, G. and Star, S.L., 2000. Sorting Things Out: classification and its consequences. Cambridge: MIT Press.
  • Bowker, G.C., et al., 2010. Toward information infrastructure studies: ways of knowing in a networked environment. In: J. Hunsinger, L. Klastrup, and M. Allen, eds. International handbook of internet research. New York City: Springer, 97–117.
  • Boyle, J.E., 1934. Cotton and the New Orleans cotton exchange: a century of commercial evolution. Garden City, NY: Country Life Press.
  • Braun, B., 2020. Central banking and the infrastructural power of finance: The case of ECB support for repo and securitization markets. Socio-Economic Review, 18, 395–418.
  • Campbell-Verduyn, M., Goguen, M., and Porter, T., 2019. Finding fault lines in long chains of financial information. Review of International Political Economy, 26, 911–937.
  • Carse, A., 2012. Nature as infrastructure: making and managing the Panama canal watershed. Social Studies of Science, 42, 539–563.
  • Chandler, A.D., 1977. The visible hand: The managerial revolution in American business. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • Cheap Telegraphing Pays, Chicago Tribune, May 26, 1886, p.9
  • Cronon, W., 1992. Nature’s metropolis: Chicago and the great west. London: WW Norton & Company.
  • de Goede, M., 2005. Virtue, fortune, and faith: A genealogy of finance. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
  • Edwards, P.N., 2003. Infrastructure and modernity: force, time, and social organization in the history of sociotechnical systems. In: T.J. Misa, P. Brey, and A Feenberg, eds. Modernity and technology. Cambridge: MIT Press, 185–226.
  • Edwards, P.N., et al., 2009. Introduction: An agenda for infrastructure studies. Journal of the Association for Information Systems, 10, 364–374.
  • Ellis, L.T., 1973. The New Orleans Cotton exchange: The formative years, 1871-1880. The Journal of Southern History, 39, 545–564.
  • Enters Telegraphic Field, Chicago Tribune, Oct. 7, 1900, p.8
  • Erturk, I., et al., 2013. (How) do devices matter in finance? Journal of Cultural Economy, 6, 336–352.
  • Fabian, A., 1999. Card sharps and bucket shops: gambling in nineteenth-century america. London: Routledge.
  • Fligstein, N., 2002. The architecture of markets: An economic Sociology of twenty-first-century capitalist societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Fourcade, M., 2007. Theories of markets and theories of society. American Behavioral Scientist, 50, 1015–1034.
  • Frost, M.O., 1926. “Hester says-” An intimate personal skethc of the world’s greatest cotton auhtority, Henry G. Hester, Secretary and superintendent of the New Orleans Cotton Exchange, for 56 years. New Orleans: The New Orleans Sunday States.
  • Guala, F., 2001. Building economic machines: The FCC auctions. Studies in History and Philosophy of Science Part A, 32, 453–477. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/S0039-3681(01)00008-5.
  • Guseva, A. and Rona-Tas, A., 2014. Plastic money: constructing markets for credit cards in eight postcommunist countries. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.
  • Hardin, C. and Rottinghaus, A.R., 2015. Introducing a cultural approach to technology in financial markets. Journal of Cultural Economy, 8, 547–563.
  • Hayes, A., 2019. The socio-technological lives of bitcoin. Theory, Culture & Society, 36, 49–72. doi:https://doi.org/10.1177/0263276419826218.
  • Hester, H.G., 1926. Cotton situation. New Orleans: New Orleans Cotton Exchange.
  • Hochfelder, D., 2006. "Where the common people could speculate": The ticker, bucket shops, and the origins of popular participation in financial markets, 1880-1920. Journal of American History, 93, 335–358. doi:https://doi.org/10.2307/4486233.
  • Jeffs, J.A., 2008. The politics of financial plumbing: harmonization and interests in the construction of the international payment system. Review of International Political Economy, 15, 259–288.
  • John, R.R., 2010. Network nation. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • Judge Wall Hearing the Case of the Board of Trade vs. Western Union at East St. Louis, Chicago Tribune, Jan. 15, 1883, p.8
  • Karasti, H., et al., 2016. Knowledge infrastructures: part I. Science & Technology Studies, 29, 2–12.
  • Kennedy, D., 2017. The machine in the market: computers and the infrastructure of price at the New York stock exchange, 1965–1975. Social Studies of Science, 47, 888–917.
  • Krarup, T., 2019. Between competition and centralization: the new infrastructures of European finance. Economy and Society, 48, 107–126.
  • Krippner, G., 2001. The elusive market: embeddedness and the paradigm of economic sociology. Theory & Society, 30, 775–810.
  • Lampland, M. and Star, S.L., 2009. Standards and their stories: How quantifying, classifying, and formalizing practices shape everyday life. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
  • Latour, B., 1988. Science in action: How to follow scientists and engineers through society. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • Law, J., 1990. Power, discretion and strategy. The Sociological Review, 38, 165–191.
  • Levy, J.I., 2006. Contemplating delivery: futures trading and the problem of commodity exchange in the United States, 1875–1905. The American Historical Review, 111, 307–335.
  • Lurie, J., 1979. The Chicago Board of Trade, 1859-1905: The dynamics of self-regulation. Urbana-Champaign: University of Illinois Press.
  • MacKenzie, D., 2018a. Material signals: A historical sociology of high-frequency trading. American Journal of Sociology, 123, 1635–1683.
  • MacKenzie, D., 2018b. Making’, ‘taking’ and the material political economy of algorithmic trading. Economy and Society, 47, 501–523.
  • MacKenzie, D, 2017. A material political economy: automated trading desk and price prediction in high-frequency trading. Social Studies of Science, 47, 172–194.
  • MacKenzie, D., 2003. An equation and its worlds: bricolage, exemplars, disunity and performativity in financial economics. Social Studies of Science, 33, 831–868. doi:https://doi.org/10.1177/0306312703336002.
  • MacKenzie, D., et al., 2012. Drilling through the allegheny mountains: liquidity, materiality and high-frequency trading. Journal of Cultural Economy, 5, 279–296.
  • MacKenzie, D. and Pardo-Guerra, J.P., 2014. Insurgent capitalism: island, bricolage and the re-making of finance. Economy and Society, 43, 153–182.
  • MacKenzie, D. and Spears, T., 2014. ‘The formula that killed wall street’: The Gaussian copula and modelling practices in investment banking. Social Studies of Science, 44, 393–417.
  • Mahoney, J., 2000. Path dependence in historical sociology. Theory and Society, 29, 507–548.
  • Markham, J.W., 2002. A financial history of the United States: from christopher columbus to the robber barons (1492–1900). Armonk, NY: ME Sharpe.
  • Markham, J.W., 1987. The History of commodity futures trading and its regulation. Westport, CT: Praeger.
  • Millo, Y., 2007. Making things deliverable: The origins of index-based derivatives. The Sociological Review, 55, 196–214. doi:https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-954X.2007.00736.x.
  • Millo, Y., et al., 2005. Organised detachment: clearinghouse mechanisms in financial markets. Information and Organization, 15, 229–246.
  • Mirowski, P. and Nik-Khah, E., 2007. Performativity, and a problem in Science studies, augmented with consideration of the FCC auctions. Econ. Make Mark. Performativity Econ, 190–224.
  • Mitchell, T., 2013. Carbon democracy: political power in the Age of Oil. London: Verso Books.
  • Muniesa, F., 2007. Market technologies and the pragmatics of prices. Economy and Society, 36, 377–395.
  • Nelms, T.C., et al., 2018. Social payments: innovation, trust, bitcoin, and the sharing economy. Theory, Culture & Society, 35, 13–33.
  • New Line of Telegraph, Chicago Tribune, Apr. 19, 1890, p.3
  • Pardo-Guerra, J.P., 2019. Automating finance: infrastructures, engineers, and the making of electronic markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Pardo-Guerra, J.P., 2015. Making markets: infrastructures, engineers and the moral technologies of finance. httpspardoguerra files wordpress Com201411141124-Mak.-mark. Pdf Acesso Em, 30, 1–96.
  • Petry, J., 2020. From national marketplaces to global providers of financial infrastructures: exchanges, infrastructures and structural power in global finance. New Political Economy, 1–24. doi:https://doi.org/10.1080/13563467.2020.1782368.
  • Pietruska, J.L., 2012. “Cotton guessers”: crop forecasters and the rationalizing of uncertainty in American cotton markets, 1890–1905. In: H. Berghoff, P. Scranton, and U. Spiekermann, eds. The rise of marketing and market research. Palgrave MacMillan: New York, 49–72.
  • Pinzur, D., 2016. Making the grade: infrastructural semiotics and derivative market outcomes on the Chicago Board of Trade and New Orleans Cotton Exchange, 1856–1909. Economy and Society, 45, 431–453.
  • Plan Lines For Their Own Use, Chicago Tribune, Jul. 31, 1900, p.5
  • Poon, M., 2009. From new deal institutions to capital markets: commercial consumer risk scores and the making of subprime mortgage finance. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34, 654–674.
  • Preda, A., 2006. Socio-technical agency in financial markets. Social Studies of Science, 36, 753–782.
  • Private New York Wires, Chicago Tribune, Jan. 30, 1887, p.14
  • Quotation War May Be Ended, Chicago Tribune, Nov. 11, 1900, p.8
  • Quotation War to Continue, Chicago Tribune, Nov. 20, 1900, p.4
  • Rella, L., 2020. Steps towards an ecology of money infrastructures: materiality and cultures of Ripple. Journal of Cultural Economics, 13, 236–249.
  • Rollins, E.S. 1920. Things You Should Know About the Chicago Board of Trade. Chicago, IL: Chicago Board of Trade.
  • Rothstein, M., 1966. Antebellum wheat and cotton exports: A contrast in marketing organization and economic development. Agricultural History, 40, 91–100.
  • Sager, H. 1908. Prosperity and the Exchange: Why the Great Trade Marts of the Country are Essential to the Conduct of Its Legitimate Business. New York, NY: Harper & Brothers.
  • Shannon, F.A., 1945. The farmer's last frontier: agriculture, 1860–1897. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, Inc.
  • Sherman, A.I., 1934. The History of the New Orleans Cotton Exchange, 1871-1914.
  • Silvast, A. and Virtanen, M.J., 2019. An assemblage of framings and tamings: multi-sited analysis of infrastructures as a methodology. Journal of Cultural Economy, 12, 461–477.
  • Star, S.L. and Ruhleder, K., 1996. Steps toward an ecology of infrastructure: design and access for large information spaces. Information Systems Research, 7, 111–134.
  • Stone, G.F. 1911. “Board of Trade of the City of Chicago.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 38, 189–204.
  • Taylor, C.H., 1917. History of the Board of Trade of the city of Chicago. Chicago: RO Law.
  • Thompson, R.L., 1947. Wiring a continent: The History of the telegraph industry in the United States, 1832-1866. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Vote For a New Telegraph Line, Chicago Tribune, Sep. 15, 1900, p.3
  • Woodman, H.D., 1963. King cotton and his retainers: financing and marketing the cotton crop of the south, 1800-1925. Washignton, DC: Beard Books.