1,609
Views
3
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

The Interplay of Family Systems, Social Networks and Fertility in Europe Cohorts Born Between 1920 and 1960

ABSTRACT

Despite important variations in regional family systems, little research has been done to assess the effects of these differences on fertility and thus on families’ economic status. Even less attention has been paid to the effects of deviating from these regionally embedded norms in terms of network compositions. People's social networks may not conform to the region's view of the ideal family, while this could have important implications for their fertility behaviour. To fill this knowledge gap, this paper aims to answer two questions: to what extent do family systems shape family size, and to what extent do deviations from regional family system norms in terms of social network composition result in differences in completed fertility? To answer these questions, we use the first two waves of the ‘Survey of Health, Aging and Retirement’ and derive indicators describing regional family systems and people's social networks. We test the influence of these covariates on the completed fertility of cohorts born between 1920 and 1960 in 13 European countries. Our results show that family system norms, and deviations from them in terms of specific social networks, play an important role in determining family size.

JEL Codes:

INTRODUCTION

Persistent regional differences in fertility can be observed across Europe. To explain the differences, researchers have drawn on economic factors (Becker & Barro Citation1988) and cultural factors (Lesthaeghe & Neels Citation2002, 349–351; Dalla Zuanna Citation2007, 442) and also on differences in family systems (Macfarlane Citation1981; Micheli Citation2005, 80; Viazzo Citation2010a, Citation2010b). Studies of the effects of family systems on fertility are rare and often limited to broad classes of family systems and to specific regions or countries (Davis Citation1955; Burch & Gendell Citation1970; Hajnal Citation1982; Das Gupta Citation1999, 181; Veleti Citation2001; Micheli Citation2005). Some have used households or co-residential units to examine family systems and their influence on behaviour (Todd Citation1990; Madhaven et al. Citation2003, 58), while especially more recent studies use indicators of social relatedness that extend beyond the household (Yorburg Citation1975; Reher Citation1998; Heady & Kohli Citation2010, 21; Viazzo Citation2010b, 144–148; Micheli Citation2012, 19). In these, and particularly in the influential study by Reher (Citation1998), family systems are framed particularly in terms of geographical variation in strong ties (with family and kin) and weak ties (with friends and relatives).

Recent research on fertility emphasizes social networks containing strong and weak ties that affect demographic behaviour (Chen Citation2006; Bühler & Fratczak Citation2007; Bernardi & White Citation2010, 181; Sear & Coall Citation2011; Keim Citation2011; Balbo Citation2012; Bernardi & Klärner Citation2014). These studies do not take family systems into account but focus rather on kin relations (for instance sibling ties) or are restricted to one region or country, limiting the possibility of comparing spatial variations in family systems (Ettrich et al. Citation1999, Kohler et al. Citation2001; Madhavan et al. Citation2003; Sear et al. Citation2003; Bühler Citation2004; Bühler & Philipov Citation2005; Bühler & Fratczak Citation2007; see Balbo Citation2012, 9).

In this article we combine both strands of research. We examine couples’ social networks, with either weak or strong ties, and look at the extent to which they conform to or deviate from the norms of the family system in their region and how this affects the couples’ fertility. Do the couples have close-knit networks containing a lot of kin, or looser-knit networks with more friends than relatives, and how does this affect fertility? Do different regional views of the ideal network composition (i.e., different family systems) have different effects on fertility? What are for instance the effects of living the same kind of social network in different family systems on the fertility? The basic research question is: if a couple's social network composition differs from the organization principles of the family system of their region, what effect does this have on their fertility? Studying the interplay between social networks and family systems and the effect of this interplay on fertility opens up a whole new perspective for understanding fertility differences in Europe.

In this paper we base our analysis on the Survey of Health, Aging and Retirement (SHARE) and derive indicators to chart regional family systems and couples’ social networks and test their influence on the completed fertility of couples born between 1920 and 1960 in 13 European countries. For the purpose of my discussion, we define family systems as the regional culturally embedded norms, values and practices that frame people's kin relationships (Mason Citation2001, 160–161), and ‘social network’ as the network of people's social interactions and relationships with their kin.

THEORETICAL BACKGROUND

Family systems, households and social networks

Family systems have long been studied on the basis of indicators that chart the organization of households and, more recently, social networks (Todd Citation1990; Reher Citation1998; Viazzo Citation2010a). Important variations and changes in family systems in and between European countries have been observed (Höllinger & Haller Citation1990; Reher Citation1998; Micheli Citation2005; Santarelli & Cottone Citation2009; Viazzo & Zanotelli Citation2010, 75; Isengard Citation2013). In Italy, for instance, it has been found that traditional co-residence of parents and children has steadily changed towards parents and children living in close proximity (Viazzo & Zanotelli Citation2010, 73–75). After leaving the parental home at a comparatively late age, children live not with but near their parents. Such developments mean that the social networks in which individuals of contemporary societies are living partly differ from the traditional notions of family systems that regard only households as being nuclear or extended. It is thus important when studying family systems to include relationships not only within but also beyond the household.

Empirical studies of the effect of social relationships and social networks on fertility show that kin beyond the household are important in structuring people's demographic behaviour (Bonvalet & Lelièvre Citation2008, 377–383; Widmer & Jallinoja, Citation2008, 397; Balbo Citation2012). Some of these studies also try to grasp the mechanisms by which family relationships may influence people's fertility, for instance through social learning, social support and social pressure (for an overview see Bernardi & Klärner Citation2014, 649–652).

‘Social learning’ refers to the way children adapt to family structures, behaviour and living strategies through socialization (Barber Citation2000, 321–322; Bernardi et al. Citation2006, 359; Groppe Citation2007, 406–407). Siblings and other family members, especially those of roughly the same age, provide behavioural examples (Axinn et al. Citation1994, 68; Bühler & Fratczak, Citation2007; Balbo Citation2012) and are an important source of knowledge (Finkel & Finkel Citation1975, 256–257; Montgomery & Casterline Citation1996, 153–154). Knowledge about fertility will include such matters as gender roles or the preferred number, timing and spacing of children (Newson & Richardson Citation2009, 9). Some effects that have been shown are a stronger desire for children in people with many nephews and nieces (Axinn et al. Citation1994, 77), a link between the fertility behaviour of siblings (Lyngstad & Prskawetz Citation2010), cross-sibling influence on the intention to have a first child (Balbo & Mills Citation2011), and substantial similarities between parents and their offspring in age of becoming a parent (Steenhof & Liefbroer Citation2008). Cross-sibling effects and similarities between parents’ and their children's fertility have been shown to be based partly on social and partly on genetic factors (Kohler et al. Citation2005; Bras et al. Citation2013, 118).

‘Social support’ refers to the role of families as organizers of solidarity and providers of welfare (Reher Citation1998, 208–209; Esping-Andersen Citation1999, 35, 47). By providing or withholding resources and services, families can reduce the risk of life course decisions and influence other family members’ fertility intentions and outcomes (Bühler & Frątczak Citation2007). The extent to which family can provide certain services is dependent on geographic distance. Some services, such as emotional support, can be provided from a distance with the help of modern communication technologies. However, most services and types of help can only be provided to family members co-residing in the household or living nearby (Litwak & Kulis Citation1987, 650; Höllinger & Haller Citation1990, 117). For example, a co-resident grandmother can take care of the grandchildren, prepare food, and help with housework (Reher Citation1998, 219–17; Sear et al. Citation2003; Tymicki Citation2004, Citation2008). Thereby, co-resident grandmothers can reduce the burden of combining work with family. Especially in social networks, where kin live in close proximity, kin, such as grandmothers, may feel more obligated to help each other, while the family is also more often used as the primary source of support (Caldwell Citation1978, 557–558; Höllinger & Haller Citation1990, 117, 120).

‘Social pressure’ refers to families’ ability to control their members’ behaviours, by pointing out norms and values and granting or withholding support. Norms may apply to such things as opportunities to meet with non-kin (Salamon Citation1977, 815–816), the use of media (Freedman et al. Citation1964, 27), courting practices (Kok Citation2009, 15), or women's roles in the family (Moore Citation1990, 726–727; Mason Citation2001, 169, 169–170; Bernardi & Oppo Citation2008, 199–201). Already the possible reactions of other family members, and the risk of being sanctioned, can influence people's behaviour and prevent outcomes undesired by the family (Ajzen Citation1991, 183; Bernardi Citation2003, 538).

Parents can have a strong influence on their offspring's fertility. In pre-transitional and transitional societiesFootnote2 the motivation for controlling fertility was often linked to household economics (Van Bavel Citation2004, 103–104; Dalla Zuanna Citation2007, 444, 448–451; Dribe & Scalone Citation2010; Amialchuck & Dimitrova Citation2012). Today, parental control over children's fertility is often linked to ‘status anxiety’, i.e., to maintain one's position on or climb the social ladder (Dalla Zuanna Citation2007). A number of studies have demonstrated a negative effect of large family size on children's educational outcomes and chances of upward social mobilityFootnote3 (for an overview see Steelman et al. Citation2002, 248ff). Among other reasons, this negative effect is explained by dilution of resources (time, material and non-material resources) among children of larger families (Blake Citation1981, 440; Steelman et al. Citation2002, 248; Bongaarts Citation2003; Micheli Citation2005; Dalla Zuanna Citation2007, 450). Facing resource constraints, parents reduce fertility to increase the share of resources for each child, thereby improving their chances to move up the social ladder (Becker & Lewis Citation1974; Becker & Barro Citation1988).

Resource dilution and reduced opportunities for social upward mobility for children are a problem particularly in regions where public childcare facilities are sparse and children's welfare is the responsibility of the family (Hilgeman & Butts Citation2009, 107; Balbo Citation2012, 100). In these regions, large family size more easily translates into a lower social status for the offspring generation since the burden of raising children is not moderated by the welfare state (Dalla Zuanna Citation2007, 451). Regions without a well-developed welfare state are also often characterized by strong family systems, with close-knit social networks, through which parents more effectively control their offspring's fertility (Granovetter Citation2005, 34, 39–40; Dalla Zuanna Citation2007, 452–453; Viazzo Citation2010b; Albertini & Kohli Citation2013). Although parents may rely on a pool of adult kin who could support and supervise children (Shavit & Pierce Citation1991, 328), social support is often limited to the co-residential unit (Albertini & Kohli Citation2013, 836), and is not necessarily linked to higher fertility (Jappens & Van Bavel Citation2012, 108–109).

Regional family systems and variance in social networks

The household organization and the organization of the wider family are associated with family systems (Reher Citation1998; Micheli Citation2005; Hank Citation2007).  Since family systems are based on culturally embedded norms, values and practices and thus frame kin relationships and determine social duties and rights (Skinner Citation1997; Das Gupta Citation1999; Mason Citation2001, 160–161; Therborn Citation2004). They create ideals of the ‘typical’ family to which families may adhere, but from which they may also deviate to a certain degree. Bott (Citation1957, 205–207, 212) demonstrated that the extent to which families were able to name such norms and how far they deviated from them depended on whether respondents lived in loose- or close-knit networks. Close-knit networks are characterized by large numbers of relatives, friends and neighbours who all know each other (1957, 59). People in close-knit networks more often refer and consent to the norms, values and family ideals shared in their social networks (Bott Citation1957, 213). In loose-knit networks fewer members know each other, and this increases the variation in social norms in their social networks (1957, 213).

According to Bott (Citation2001, 295–296), relationships to kin are more likely to be close-knit and permanent than relationships to non-kin, which are more easily dissolved. Regions with strong family systems are thus more likely to be characterized by close-knit social networks, dominated by kin relationships, than those with weak family systems (Reher Citation1998; Micheli Citation2005; Viazzo Citation2010b). In strong family regions, family members are more likely to share the same family norms and values and be able to enforce them more easily, which results in more commonly agreed upon family organization principles. In weak family regions, social networks contain a greater variety of relationships with both kin and non-kin (Höllinger & Haller Citation1990; Mönkediek & Bras Citation2014) and a greater spatial dispersion between kin is observed (Viazzo Citation2010b, 147). This greater dispersion is often connected with a more generous welfare state, which allows for greater intergenerational transfers of resources and reduces the need for kin co-residence (Albertini & Kohli Citation2013). Since social norms are less coherent and less enforced in weak family regions, we expect a greater variety of social networks in these areas. Hence, we expect that variation in families’ social networks is greater in weak than in strong family regions (H1).

In line with hypothesis 1 above, we expect people's ideas about living strategies and family organization to be more diverse in weak family regions, because their networks contain a greater share of non-kin. We assume that this also results in greater variability in fertility, since non-kin in social networks often link individuals to more distant networks parts, exposing them to different life concepts (as demonstrated by Newson et al. Citation2005, Citation2007). Accordingly, we expect that differences in family size are more pronounced in weak family regions than in strong family regions (H2).

Family ideals and experiences that are transmitted from generation to generation will steer people's attitudes towards family organization and children (Johnson & Stokes Citation1976, 176). Since social interactions between kin are closer and families are more highly valued in strong family regions, we would expect processes of socialization to raise fertility in these regions. However, empirical research has shown that in societies in which group norms are more easily enforced, social norms ‘overrule’ the effects of socialization (Van Bavel & Kok Citation2009, 357). In such societies, a positive socialization effect seems to be counteracted by a higher burden of social support and by mismatches between family ideals and realities. This is the case, for example, in many Mediterranean countries. In these countries, public childcare is sparse and the provision of welfare is seen as a family duty (Hilgeman & Butts Citation2009, 107; Balbo Citation2012, 100). At the same time, these countries favour family ideals and criteria for starting a family that are more complex and more difficult to conform to (Newson Citation2009, 470). For the case of Italy, Livi-Bacci (Citation2001, 149) has shown that during the mid-twentieth century certain life-course ideals developed that made setting up one's own household and acquiring a full-time job a precondition for getting married and having children. Nonetheless, many young Italians postponed setting up their own households because of the better economic circumstances in the parental household, the emotional closeness to their parents and the limited availability of independent living space on the housing market (Livi-Bacci Citation2001, 146–148; Dalla Zuanna Citation2004, 111–115; Vignoli et al. Citation2013).

In strong family regions we expect socialization effects to be counteracted by economic realities, since the welfare state facilities are insufficient to support the current family ideals and desired living styles. In weak family regions, by contrast, such effects may indeed play a role. The extensive public child care and welfare state provision reduces the burden of raising children, which limits the need to control offspring's fertility. Accordingly, a more generous welfare state allows for socialization effects that increase people's desire for children. Finally, the more individualized family lifestyle not only fosters greater variety in the composition of families’ social networks but also results in higher fertility. Our hypothesis for testing these assumptions is that couples with close-knit networks have higher levels of completed fertility in weak than in strong family regions (H3).

DATA, MEASURES AND METHODS

Data

We used the first two waves of the Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe (SHARE) to answer our research questions and test our hypothesis. The first wave was conducted in 2004/05 in 11 European countries (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Netherlands, Spain, Sweden and Switzerland) and Israel. The second wave, conducted in 2006/07, contained a panel and a replication component, adding three more countries to the survey (Ireland, Poland and the Czech Republic). Together the two waves contain 31,168 respondents who can be identified as anchor persons (APs). Of these cases, 13,678 belong to the panel segment. Apart from the information on APs, the datasets contain information on members of the APs’ households, and also modules that capture respondents’ social relationships (for example, by asking about help relationships). The target population of the survey was 50 years and older, allowing for the study of completed fertility histories.

The following analysis includes APs from only 13 European countries.Footnote4 Persons born before 1920 and after 1960 had to be omitted from the analysis due to low case numbers (1,014 cases), limiting our analysis to cohorts born between 1920 and 1960. To make reliable statements about respondents’ fertility and their location in Europe, we also excluded respondents with missing information on completed fertility (616 cases) or missing NUTS codesFootnote5 (516 cases). Applying these selection criteria reduced N from 31,168 to 26,407 cases. In the regression analysis this number is even lower due to variable non-response. Moreover, some NUTS regions had to be excluded from the regression models because of very low case numbersFootnote6 – leaving 15,252 cases. of shows the number of included cases per NUTS region.

Measures

Dependent variable

The dependent variable in our analysis is the couple's completed fertility, which was charted by asking respondents about the number of living children. lists the countries and cohorts. It shows that average completed fertility in the SHARE survey was 2.054. Austria, Germany, Italy and Greece lie clearly below this European average, while the Netherlands, Sweden, Spain, France and Denmark have higher values.Footnote7 Fertility in the overall European cohort decreases over time, from 2.178 (birth cohort 1920–30) to 1.914 (birth cohort 1951–60). Looking at country-specific developments, we see a more complex picture. In France and Austria, for example, cohort fertility fluctuates over birth cohorts. In some other countries, such as Germany and the Netherlands, we see an overall decrease in cohort fertility, while in other countries, such as France and Sweden, fertility even increases.

Table 1: Average completed fertility per country and cohort

Explanatory and control variables

Our main explanatory variables are two variables that take into account the geographical distance and the intensity of social relationships (frequency of social contact) between respondents and their kin. These variables, which reflect respondents’ kinship networks, are also used to derive indicators of regional family systems.

The strength of kin relationships varies with the spatial and social distance (De Jong Gierveld & Fokkema, Citation1998, 332; Heady et al. Citation2010; Dykstra & Fokkema, Citation2011, 549–550). Close kin relationships are likely to increase the effectiveness of mechanisms of social learning or social control due to increased social interaction and increased social support (Granovetter Citation2005: 34, 39–40). To differentiate between different social networks, we derive two indicators that describe the geographical distance and the intensity of social relationships (frequency of social contact) between respondents and their kin. These indicators measure the social and geographical density of social networks on a continuum. This has the advantage of enabling us to identify a much broader variety of networks, since we do not use categories of predefined types. The indicators range from networks characterized by spatially and socially close relationships between kin (close-knit kinship networks) to networks that consist of very sparse connections between kin (loose-knit kinship networks) (Mönkediek & Bras Citation2014, 34–35).

To derive these indicators we use the information in the SHARE survey on the frequency of contact in and geographical proximity of respondents’ current

  1. co-residential relationships, i.e. individuals living in the respondents’ households,

  2. relationships to parents (if alive),

  3. relationships to children (if they had any),Footnote8

  4. relationships to (up to three) persons to whom they had provided any kind of help in the past 12 months,

  5. relationships to (up to three) persons who provided the respondents with any kind of help during the past 12 months.

In contrast to earlier research on kinship networks based on geographical proximity and frequency of social contact, we include all the above described relationships and do not limit our study to specific family members or subsamples.Footnote9

For the first indicator, average contact, for all kin relationships we add up the frequency of social contact and divided by the sum of all social ties in the network. In this way we create a personal mean value for each respondent, reflecting the density of the kinship network (Mönkediek & Bras Citation2014, 35). The variables capturing the frequency of contact between respondents and their alter-egos range from (1) ‘daily’ contact to (7) ‘never’ having contact.Footnote10 For co-resident relationships, where no information on the frequency of social contact was provided, we assume ‘frequent’ social contact, as the probability of meeting each other every day was rather high. After rescaling our variable, a higher score of our family system indicator reflects on average more frequent social contact between kin. It now ranges from one (‘no contact’ with existing family and kin members) to seven (‘very frequent’ contact).

For the second indicator, average spatial proximity, we count all family relationships, added up the spatial proximity scores, and divide their sum by the number of all family ties in the network, thus creating a mean value reflecting the spatial density of the family network (Mönkediek & Bras Citation2014, 35–36). The original variables, which contain the information on spatial proximity between kin, range from (1) ‘in the same household’ to (9) ‘more than 500 km away in another country’.Footnote11 Our constructed variable ranges from one to nine, with a higher value indicating closer spatial proximity between couples and their kin.

Aggregating our two network indicators to the regional level (NUTS 2), we derive two parameters of regional family systems. shows the mean values of our network indicators for the European countries – thus showing regional family systems per country. Looking more closely at the two parameters, we identify three clusters of European countries: the first consisting of France, Sweden and Denmark, the second of the Netherlands, Germany, Switzerland, Belgium, Austria and the Czech Republic, and the third of the Mediterranean countries (Greece, Spain and Italy). Poland seems to score in between the Mediterranean and the central European cluster. As higher values of both indicators reflect networks that are more family-centred, our results confirm other research findings of strong family bonds in the Mediterranean and weak family ties in the Nordic countries (Höllinger & Haller Citation1990; Reher Citation1998).

Figure 1: Average kinship network density in European countries (identifying family systems)

Figure 1: Average kinship network density in European countries (identifying family systems)

As well as our main explanatory variables, we include several control variables in our analysis (see ).

Table 2: Descriptive statistics (control variables)

Birth cohort is included to account for changing effects of family networks over time. We differentiate between the following birth cohort groups, with the youngest as the reference category: 1920–30, 1931–40, 1941–50, 1951–60. In the different countries, between 56 and 69% of the respondents were born between 1931 and 1950.

Country. Country dummies are included to control for national differences in fertility behaviour.

Degree of urbanization. Previous research has shown that networks tend to be more familial dense in rural areas (Höllinger & Haller, Citation1990, 112, 119). To control for this, we construct a dummy variable measuring whether the respondent's current place of residence is urban or rural.

Educational level. Differences in completed fertility may also be the result of socioeconomic status, as has been found in previous research (Danziger & Neumann Citation1989, 25; Anderton et al. Citation1987). To control for social status effects we include respondents’ education, measured by the ISCED-97 classification.Footnote12 The categories ‘first stage tertiary’ and ‘second stage tertiary’ are pooled because of low numbers. In our dataset about 30.7% of the respondents have pre-primary or primary education, about 48% have lower or upper secondary education, and 21.3% have tertiary education, reflecting the expected educational distribution for the included birth cohorts. Looking at country averages (weighted), we find differences in education between respondents in Denmark and Germany and those in the Mediterranean countries, with the former having a higher average level of education. This may be partly due to differences in the countrywise distribution of the included birth cohorts.

Finally, variances in the fertility levels of respondents from different European regions may be the result of socioeconomic characteristics of these regions. To control for such differences, we include in my models the regional Purchasing Power Standard per inhabitant (PPS) for the year 2000. These regional values are derived from Eurostat.Footnote13 Although these data do not reflect the socioeconomic characteristics of a region during the reproductive lifespan of the respondents, they are still a valuable indicator of socioeconomic disparities, which appear to be relatively persistent.

Methods

Before we could test our hypotheses using regression analysis, we had to solve three problems. The first was the coexistence of different sampling methods in the target countries of the SHARE waves. We solved this problem by weighting our coefficients using the weights included in the SHARE survey (Klevmarker et al. Citation2005). The second problem was that the respondents’ social relationships and family size were measured at the same point in time, after they had completed their fertility. In addition, respondents’ social networks include relationships to their children. Both aspects lead to a problem possible reversed causality (endogeneity), represented by the form:

Earlier research has reported significant differences in parent-offspring relationships between regions with different family systems (Hank Citation2007). Parent-offspring relationships can thus be used to identify differences in regional family systems and, related to this, differences in kinship networks. Nevertheless, to deal with both issues we decided to use an instrumental variables (IV) regression, which is applicable when regressors are endogenous or mismeasured and standard inferential methods are invalid (Ebbes et al. Citation2009, 446; Lewbel Citation2012, 67). In this study we use Lewbel's approach (LA) (Lewbel Citation2012), which can be applied when no instruments or only weak instruments are present. Using information on the heteroscedasticity in the data, instruments are generated out of existing variables by multiplying the heteroscedastic error terms from a first stage regression with the subset of mean-centred exogenous regressors (Z) (Lewbel Citation2012, 73; Brown Citation2014, 38). (See Appendix 2 for a more detailed description of Lewbel's approach (LA) and a test of its assumptions.)

The LA has one drawback: its estimates are less reliable than those of traditional IV models (Lewbel Citation2012, 67). Following Lewbel's (Citation2012, 77) suggestion, we therefore augment our approach by including one traditional instrument found in the dataset. This improves the model's estimation efficiency. In this study we use people's opinions about the provision of welfare. Respondents were asked to indicate, on a scale of one to five, whether the state, the family, or a mixture of the two should ‘give financial support’, ‘help with household chores’ and ‘provide personal care’ for older persons in need (Cronbach's alpha = 0.80). The resulting variable ‘welfare orientation’ is nearly normally distributed (mean 3.095, std. err. 0.009), and correlated with the network indicators but not with respondent's completed fertility. Unfortunately, a lot of values are missing from this variable, reducing the N in our analysis from 24,036 to 15,252 cases.

The third problem was that we had to take the hierarchical structure of the SHARE dataset into account. Individuals are nested in NUTS 2 regions, which are nested in countries. The LA is based on the specification that the number of instruments (including all exogenous regressors) is not larger than the number of clusters in the dataset – otherwise this would lead to problems in the identification of the model (Baum et al. Citation2007, 485). In our case, we only have 13 countries, which constitute the highest level of clustering. This number lies below the various rules of thumb for the number of clusters needed to get consistent estimates of the standard errors within multi-level regression models (Stegmueller Citation2013; Cameron & Miller Citation2011). In addition, the number of instruments generated from our control variables exceeds the number of countries. To estimate our models successfully and reduce the number of clusters needed for model identification, we first partialed out the effects of the control variables in the regression models. To account for the clustered data structure, we included country fixed effects (Cameron & Miller Citation2011, Citation2013, 19). Since these effects do not completely capture all within-country correlation of the error term (Cameron & Miller 2013, 16), we also derived cluster robust error terms at NUTS 2 levels, to further correct the estimates.

RESULTS

Descriptive results

In order to test our first hypothesis (H1), that variation in families’ social networks is greater in weak than in strong family regions, we created a variable to capture the variation (variance) in contact frequency and spatial proximity between kin in each NUTS 2 region.Footnote14 Looking at the averages (see ), we find little variation in couples’ social networks in Sweden and in strong family countries such as Spain and Italy. There is more variation in spatial proximity between kin in Greece. Interestingly, we also observe large variation in frequency of contact between kin in Denmark, though the average variation in spatial proximity is comparatively low. Apart from that, the variation in network indicators is comparatively high in most central European countries, as represented by their country averages (Austria, Germany, France and Switzerland). Thus, in contrast to our expectation, variation in social networks is not necessarily higher in weak than in strong family countries, which already rejects our first hypothesis (H1).

Figure 2: Regional variance in contact frequency and spatial proximity between kin (NUTS 2), per country

Figure 2: Regional variance in contact frequency and spatial proximity between kin (NUTS 2), per country

Intriguingly, we observe strong regional differences within most European countries as described by the boxplots. While the differences in social networks among Swedish regions are rather small, in Italy, Poland, Spain, Greece, France and Germany they are quite large. Comparing regions, we observe many outliers in Germany, Greece and Spain, suggesting important regional differences in family systems. Mapping those differences (see and ), the divergences between Italian regions seem to follow the standard division of Italy into two Italian family systems, which has also been observed by several other researchers (for an overview see Micheli Citation2012, 30–31). In northern Italy, where the stem family model prevails (Micheli Citation2012, 30), we observe very little variation in spatial proximity among kin. At the same time, we observe large variation in proximity among kin in southern Italian regions, where children leave home and establish their own households earlier, but stay in close proximity to their parents (Santarelli & Cottone Citation2009, 6–8; Micheli Citation2012, 30). This result is less clear with respect to variations in frequency of contact among kin (see ). Looking at these two regions and comparing their fertility levels, we observe higher fertility in the southern Italian regions of Calabria (2.480), Campania (2.562) and Sicilia (2.211) and on average smaller family sizes in the northern parts of Italy (Emilia-Romagna: 1.602, Liguria: 1.190, Lombardy: 1.670). Interestingly, these regional differences follow the diverse and persistent pattern of regional fertility decline, observed by Peréz and Livi-Bacci (1992, 164). While the regional pattern in Italy suggests that fertility levels are higher in regions with more variability in social networks, for Spain and Greece this picture is much less clear. For most parts of Spain, the picture is even reversed. Fertility is lower in regions with more variation in social networks (Galicia: 1.886, Castile and León: 1.901, Aragón: 1.850) and higher in regions with less variation (Andalucía: 2.830, Murcia: 2.754, Navarra: 2.537). Only in a few Spanish regions (Catalonia: 2.241, Valencia: 2.016) variability in social networks and fertility levels are high.

Figure 3: Regional variance in families’ social networks based on spatial proximity

Figure 3: Regional variance in families’ social networks based on spatial proximity

Figure 4: Regional variance in families’ social networks based on frequency of contact

Figure 4: Regional variance in families’ social networks based on frequency of contact

Finally, it is not only fertility that is lower in regions characterized by more variation in social networks; there is a significant negative association between regional variance in spatial proximity among kin and variation in family size (rho: –0.063; P = 0.000). This rejects my second hypothesis (H2), that differences in family size are more pronounced in weak family regions than in strong family regions. The results show that variation in family size is not necessarily greater in weak family regions.

Regression results

and present the results of using the LA and the augmented LA (LA+) and also OLS estimates for each model for further comparison. In all models the effects of the control variables were partialed out to reduce the number of excluded instruments. The test of the model assumptions is described in Appendix 2. As reported, all model assumptions are fulfilled.

Table 3: Instrumental variables regression results, explaining regional fertility variation

First of all, the effects of the network indicators on completed fertility (), suggest that deviations in social networks from the regional means (family systems) have a significant effect on people's fertility. Individuals whose networks are characterized by closer proximity between kin than the regional averages would suggest, have significantly lower fertility (models 3.2 and 3.3). Interestingly, we find no direct effects of the family systems variables on family size. Yet, as demonstrated by models 3.2 and 3.3, there is an effect of regional variance in social networks on fertility. In regions with more variation in social networks, fertility is lower, thus reducing possible variation in fertility, too. Hence, not only the degree to which individuals deviate from regional family systems matters, but also the regional coherence in social networks is of importance.

To test our third hypothesis (H3), that couples with close-knit networks have higher levels of completed fertility in weak than in strong family regions, we include two interaction terms in our models. These terms link deviations in social network composition with differences in the regional means (reflecting different family systems). The results (models 4.2 and 4.3 in ) show that a network with spatially closer ties to kin than the regional average has a negative effect on couples’ fertility. This effect turns out to be different from what we expected. Since there is the possibility that this general effect is different between weak and strong family systems, we also test how far the effect varies between such regions. Looking at the interaction term suggests no significant changes in the effects. Hypothesis H3 is therefore rejected.

Table 4: Instrumental variables regression results, explaining completed fertility

Finally, we test how far there are changes in the effects of deviating from regional family system norms in terms of social network composition between regions with more or less variation in social networks. We therefore include another interaction term. The results show (models 4.5 and 4.6 of ) a positive interaction effect for differences in frequency of contact between kin and the regional variance in social networks. This effect is again significant (p = 0.015), suggesting that the negative direct effect of deviating from regional family system norms is absorbed by contact frequency to kin (p = 0.029) in regions characterized by more variation.

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

The central question of this article was: to what extent does the interplay of regional family systems and social networks shape the fertility behaviour of people born between 1920 and 1960? We measured the structure of social networks using two network indicators which reflect the average frequency of social contact and the average geographical proximity among respondents and their kin. Aggregating these measures on regional levels (NUTS 2) provided us with indicators reflecting regional family systems. Comparing social networks of individuals with the derived regional indicators, we were able to identify the degree to which individuals’ networks deviated from regional family system norms and how this influenced their fertility. We tested the effects of regional family systems and family network indicators on fertility using the instrument free Lewbel's approach (LA) (Lewbel Citation2012). This approach is new to demographic studies, but its usefulness has been demonstrated in other disciplines (Rigobon Citation2003, 77; Rigobon & Roderik Citation2005, 536; Emran & Shilpi Citation2012, 1136). The results of our regression models suggest that both regional family systems and couples’ social networks play a role, influencing completed fertility.

Regional family systems play a role in that they lay down the ideals of the ‘normal’ family from which couples’ social networks could differ. While the impact of the indicators (distance from and social contact with kin in social networks) measuring regional family systems on fertility turned out to be insignificant, our results demonstrated that deviations from these regional family system norms in terms of social network composition influenced couple's fertility significantly. However, contradicting our expectations, closer ties to kin led to lower fertility in all family system regions and not only in strong family systems as we had expected. Although this result seems to confirm the negative effect of closer family bonds on fertility (Livi-Bacci Citation2001), it is puzzling to see that this effect was the same in weak and strong family regions.

Mapping the variance of the two network indicators in each NUTS region, we observed a greater variability in couples’ social networks according to distance from and contacts with kin) in the central and most southern European regions ( and ). This descriptive result is surprising too, because it was the opposite of what we had expected. We expected to observe a greater variety in social networks, which would result in higher fertility in the weak family regions. Surprisingly, in the weak family northern European regions the coherence in social networks turned out to be comparatively strong. The more individualized life concepts, together with the more generous welfare state of the Scandinavian countries (Reher Citation1998; Albertini & Kohli Citation2013), may in fact have reduced the range of family configurations. Together, these factors seem to support the extant norms of living separated from kin, which facilitates networks where kin tend to live outside the household, but in close proximity (Albertini & Kohli Citation2013).

At the same time, the steady nuclearization of for instance Italian families (Viazzo Citation2010b, 146), seems to result in less coherence in social networks. For the Mediterranean countries, we observed important regional differences in family systems and coherence in social networks. This corroborates the already observed variations in family organization between, for example, Italian regions (Viazzo Citation2010b, 146; Viazzo & Zanotelli Citation2010; Micheli, Citation2012). The lower fertility in the strong family regions and the greater variety in social networks can be linked again to the welfare state. Especially in the strong family Mediterranean countries, the welfare state increased the differences among regional family ideals and styles of living, leading to fertility postponement (Livi-Bacci Citation2001, 146–148; Vignoli et al. Citation2013).

The better fit between family norms and lifestyles in the weak family Nordic countries might explain why we observed a negative effect of stronger family ties on fertility. The better fit leads to higher fertility, while the misfit between family norms and lifestyles in the strong family Mediterranean countries reduces it. From this point of view, there seems to be no positive effect on fertility of living in close-knit family networks in weak family regions, as long as family in proximity provide practical and emotional support. Yet this could be different again in regions where family system norms allow for a greater variety in networks, such as in the central European ones (Albertini & Kohli Citation2013, 836).

Thus our results demonstrate that the negative effect of closer bonds (based on contact frequency) on fertility is weaker in regions characterized by less cohesion in social networks. Particularly in central European countries cohesion is rather weak. This result corroborates the idea that closer bonds in weak family regions support fertility when the context is right. This context seems to be the link between regional family norms, the welfare state which frames couples’ socioeconomic context and the actual family organization. In the central European regions, the misfit between family ideals (family systems) and family organization seems to be less pronounced than in the Mediterranean countries. At the same time, familial support does not stop at the household border, as it does in many Mediterranean countries (Albertini & Kohli Citation2013, 836). Given the traditional welfare state, there is thus still added value in living in close-knit family networks in these parts of Europe, which could increase fertility.

Our research contributes to understanding the persistent regional differences in fertility levels and fertility behaviour across Europe. To understand these spatial differences, our study related people's fertility decisions to the regional conceptions of family and kin as anchored in family systems and to people's actual social networks and the role family plays in them. The results show that we can improve on previous research into regional fertility differences by measuring people's complete social networks and not just their household composition. Our results show that family system norms, and deviations from them in terms of specific social networks, play an important role in determining family size. However, our findings also suggest that in order to better explain the interplay between family systems, social networks and fertility, we need also to take into consideration the national welfare state or organization. This is an important alternative source of welfare which may mediate the interplay among family systems, social networks and fertility in important ways. Hence future research should investigate this issue further by theorizing the possible linkages and testing them by including information on welfare organization.

Notes

2 Pre-transitional and transitional societies are defined as societies before and during the modern fertility transition.

3 This effect is more variable in pre-transitional societies or developing countries (Van Bavel et al. Citation2011; Lawson & Mace Citation2011, 334).

4 Ireland had to be excluded from the analysis due to missing NUTS codes for some APs.

5 NUTS (Nomenclature of Units for Territorial Statistics) is a hierarchical system dividing the Europe Union into clusters of comparable population size according to the administrative divisions laid down by the EU member states. Each country code starts with the international letter code for that country.

Sources: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/nuts_nomenclature/introduction; http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/nuts_nomenclature/local_administrative_units (accessed 14 November 2014).

6 These were the Spanish regions of Cantabria, La Rioja and Ceuta, the French regions of Midi-Pyrenees and Corse, and the Polish regions of Lodzkie and Lubelskie (altogether 32 cases).

7 The result for Spain is not surprising, because fertility decline in Spain started slightly later than in other Mediterranean countries (Pérez & Livi-Bacci Citation1992).

8 For relationships to children, ‘frequency of social contact’ was gathered in the survey only for the first four children and information on ‘spatial proximity of parents to their children’ was gathered for all children.

9 Hank (Citation2007, 171) included only the child with the closest spatial or social contact in his analysis. Kohli et al. (Citation2005) mostly did the same. Dykstra and Fokkema (Citation2011) created their typology on the basis of (1) whether parents had a child living within a 5km range, while having contact with at least one of their children every week, (2) whether respondents felt highly responsible for caring for their children or grandchildren and (3) the direction of intergenerational transfers, applying latent-class-analysis (LCA). They also restricted their sample to respondents with at least one child without parent-child co-residence (Dykstra & Fokkema Citation2011, 551–553).

10 The variables differentiate between the categories: (1) daily, (2) several times a week, (3) about once a week, (4) about every two weeks, (5) about once a month, (6) less than once a month, and (7) never having contact.

11 The variables differentiate between the categories: (1) ‘in the same household’, (2) ‘in the same building’, (3) less than 1km away, (4) between 1 and 5km, (5) between 5 and 25km, (6) between 25 and 100km, (7) between 100 and 500km, (8) more than 500km, and (9) more than 500km in another country.

12 For more information on ISCED-97 see: http://www.unesco.org/education/information/nfsunesco/doc/isced_1997.htm (accessed 18 February 2015).

14 For Germany information was only available on NUTS 1 levels. For Denmark, where the information was available on NUTS3 levels, we aggregated regions into three higher clusters (north, west, south and east Denmark).

References

  • Ajzen, I, 1991. The theory of planned behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 50, 179–211. doi: 10.1016/0749-5978(91)90020-T
  • Albertini, M & Kohli, M, 2013. The generational contract in the family: An analysis of transfer regimes in Europe. European Sociological Review 29(4), 828–840. doi: 10.1093/esr/jcs061
  • Amialchuck, A & Dimitrova, E, 2012. Detecting the evolution of deliberate fertility control before the demographic transition in Germany. Demographic Research 27 (19), 507–542. doi: 10.4054/DemRes.2012.27.19
  • Anderton, DL, Tsuya, NO, Bean LL & Mineau, GP, 1987. Intergenerational transmission of relative fertility and life course patterns. Demography 24(4), 467–480. doi: 10.2307/2061386
  • Axinn, WG, Clarkberg, ME & Thornton, A, 1994. Family influence on family size preferences. Demography 31(1), 65–79. doi: 10.2307/2061908
  • Balbo, N, 2012. Family friends and fertility. PhD dissertation, University of Groningen, Ridderprint, Ridderkerk.
  • Balbo, N & Mills, M, 2011. The influence of the family network on the realization of fertility intentions. Vienna Yearbook of Population Research 9, 179–206. doi: 10.1553/populationyearbook2011s179
  • Barber, JS, 2000. Intergenerational influences on the entry into parenthood. Social Forces 79(1), 319–348. doi: 10.1093/sf/79.1.319
  • Baum, CF, Schaffer, ME & Stillman, S, 2007. Enhanced routines for instrumental variables/generalized method of moments estimation and testing. Stata Journal 7(4), 465–506.
  • Baum, CF & Schaffer, ME, 2012. ivreg2h: Stata module to perform instrumental variables estimation using heteroskedasticity-based instruments. Available online: http://ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s457555.html (accessed 16 February 2015).
  • Becker, GS & Lewis, HG, 1974. Interaction between quantity and quality of children. In Schultz, TW (Ed), Economics of the family: Marriage, children, and human. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, 81–90.
  • Becker, GS & Barro, RJ, 1988. A reformulation of the economic theory of fertility. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 103(1), 1–25. doi: 10.2307/1882640
  • Bernardi, L, 2003. Channels of social influence on reproduction. Population Research and Policy Review 22, 527–555. doi: 10.1023/B:POPU.0000020892.15221.44
  • Bernardi, L & Oppo, A, 2008. Female-centered family configurations and fertility. In Widmer, ED & Jallinoja, R (Eds), Beyond the nuclear family: Families in a configurational perspective. Peter Lang, Bern, Berlin, Brussels, 178–206.
  • Bernardi, L & White, R, 2010. Close kin influences on fertility behaviour. In Heady, P & Kohli, M (Eds), Family, kinship and state in contemporary Europe. Perspectives on theory and policy. Campus, Frankfurt, 177–201.
  • Bernardi, L & Klärner, A, 2014. Social networks and fertility. Demographic Research 30(22), 641–670. doi: 10.4054/DemRes.2014.30.22
  • Bernardi, L, Keim, S & von der Lippe, H, 2006. Freunde, Familie und das eigene Leben: Zum Einfluss sozialer Netzwerke auf die Lebens- und Familienplanung junger Erwachsener in Lübeck und Rostock. In Hollstein, B & Straus, F (Eds), Qualitative Netzwerkanalyse – Konzepte, Methoden, Anwendungen. Wiesbaden, VS-Verlag, 359–390.
  • Blake, J, 1981. Family size and the quality of children. Demography 18(4), 421–442. doi: 10.2307/2060941
  • Bongaarts, J, 2003. Completing the fertility transition in the developing world: The role of educational differences and fertility preferences. Population Studies 57(3), 321–335. doi: 10.1080/0032472032000137835
  • Bonvalet, C & Lelièvre, E, 2008. Entourage: A web of relationships in reference spaces. In Widmer, ED & Jallinoja, R (Eds), Beyond the nuclear family: Families in a configurational perspective. Peter Lang, Bern, Berlin, Brussels, 375–396.
  • Bott, E, 1957. Family and social networks. Tavistock, London.
  • Bott, E, 2001. Family and social networks. Reprint. Routledge, Oxon.
  • Bras, H, Van Bavel, J & Mandemakers, K, 2013. Unravelling the intergenerational transmission of fertility: Genetic and shared-environment effects during the demographic transition in the Netherlands, 1810–1910. The History of the Family. doi:10.1080/1081602X.2013.803491
  • Brown, TT, 2014. How effective are public health departments at preventing mortality? Economics and Human Biology 13, 34–45. doi: 10.1016/j.ehb.2013.10.001
  • Bühler, C, 2004. Die Nutzung sozialer Netzwerke in unsicheren Situationen: Entscheidungen über Fertilität und Familienplanung in Kenia. In Diekmann, A & Voss, T (Eds), Rational Choice Theorie in den Sozialwissenschaften. Anwendungen und Probleme. Munich, Oldenbourg, 309–330.
  • Bühler, C & Fratczak, E, 2007. Learning from others and receiving support: The impact of personal networks on fertility intentions in Poland. European Societies 9(3), 359–382. doi: 10.1080/14616690701314101
  • Bühler, C & Philipov, D, 2005. Social capital related to fertility: Theoretical foundations and empirical evidence from Bulgaria. In Vienna Yearbook of Population Research 2005. Wien, Austrian Academy of Science Press, 53–81.
  • Burch, TK & Gendell, M, 1970. Extended family structure and fertility: Some conceptual and methodological issues. Journal of Marriage and Family 32(2), 227–236. doi: 10.2307/350128
  • Caldwell, JC, 1978. A theory of fertility: From high plateau to destabilization. Population and Development Review 4(4), 553–577. doi: 10.2307/1971727
  • Cameron, AC & Miller, DL, 2011. Robust inference with clustered data. In Ullah, A & Giles, DEA (Eds), Handbook of empirical economics and finance. Chapman & Hall, Boca Raton, 1–28.
  • Cameron, AC & Miller, D, 2013. A practitioner's guide to cluster-robust inference. Journal of Human Resources 50(2), 317–372.
  • Chen, F, 2006. The impact of family structure on fertility. In Poston, DL, Lee, CF, Chang, CF, McKibben, SL & Walther, CS (Eds), Fertility, family planning, and population policy in China. Routledge, London, 53–64.
  • Dalla Zuanna, G, 2004. The banquet of Aeolus: A familistic interpretation of Italy's lowest low fertility. In Dalla Zuanna, G & Micheli, GA (Eds), Strong family and low fertility: A paradox? Kluwer, Alphen, 105–125.
  • Dalla Zuanna, G, 2007. Social mobility and fertility. Demographic Research 17(15), 441–64. doi: 10.4054/DemRes.2007.17.15
  • Das Gupta, M, 1999. Lifeboat versus corporate ethic: Social and demographic implications of stem and joint families. Social Science & Medicine 49, 173–84. doi: 10.1016/S0277-9536(99)00096-9
  • Danziger, L & Neuman, S, 1989. Intergenerational effects on fertility: Theory and evidence from Israel. Journal of Population Economy 2, 25–37. doi: 10.1007/BF00599178
  • Davis, K, 1955. Institutional patterns favoring high fertility in underdeveloped areas. Eugenics Quarterly 2, 33–39. doi: 10.1080/19485565.1955.9987218
  • De Jong Gierveld, J & Fokkema, T, 1998. Geographical differences in support networks of older adults. Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie 89(3), 328–336. doi: 10.1111/1467-9663.00032
  • Denny, K & Oppedisano, V, 2013. The surprising effect of larger class sizes: Evidence using two identification strategies. Labour Economics 23, 57–65. doi: 10.1016/j.labeco.2013.04.004
  • Dribe, M & Scalone, F, 2010. Detecting deliberate fertility control in pre-transitional populations: Evidence from six German villages, 1766–1863. European Journal of Population 26(4), 411–434. doi: 10.1007/s10680-010-9208-8
  • Dykstra, PA & Fokkema, T, 2011. Relationships between parents and their adult children: A West European typology of late-life families. Ageing and Society 31, 545–569. doi: 10.1017/S0144686X10001108
  • Ebbes, P, Wedel, M & Böckenholt, U, 2009. Frugal IV alternatives to identify the parameter for an endogenous regressor. Journal of Applied Econometrics 24, 446–468. doi: 10.1002/jae.1058
  • Emran, MS & Shilpi, F, 2012. The extent of the market and stages of agricultural specialization. Canadian Journal of Economics 45(3), 1125–1153. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-5982.2012.01729.x
  • Esping-Andersen, G, 1999. Social foundations of postindustrial economies. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
  • Ettrich, KU, Mageda Anwer, K & Ettrich, C, 1999. Bedeutung sozialen Netzwerke beim Übergang zur Elternschaft in Ost-Deutschland und der Jemenitischen Arabischen Republik. In Reichle, B & Werneck, H (Eds), Übergang zur Elternschaft: Aktuelle Studien zur Bewältigung eines unterschätzten Lebensereignisses. Enke-Verlag, Stuttgart, 93–108.
  • Finkel, ML & Finkel, DJ, 1975. Sexual and contraceptive knowledge, attitudes and behavior of male adolescents. Family Planning Perspectives 7(6), 256–260. doi: 10.2307/2133651
  • Freedman, R, Takeshita, JY & Sun, TH, 1964. Fertility and family planning in Taiwan: A case study of the demographic transition. American Journal of Sociology 70(1), 16–27. doi: 10.1086/223734
  • Granovetter, M, 2005. The impact of social structure on economic outcomes. Journal of Economic Perspectives 19(1), 33–50. doi: 10.1257/0895330053147958
  • Groppe, C, 2007. Familiengedächnisse und Familienstrategien. In Ecarius, J (Ed), Handbuch Familie. VS-Verlag, Wiesbaden, 406–423.
  • Hank, K, 2007. Proximity and contacts between older parents and their children: A European comparison. Journal of Marriage and Family 69, 157–173. doi: 10.1111/j.1741-3737.2006.00351.x
  • Hajnal, J, 1982. Two kinds of preindustrial household formation system. Population and Development Review 8(3), 449–494. doi: 10.2307/1972376
  • Heady, P & Kohli, M, 2010. Introduction: towards a political economy of kinship and welfare. In Heady, P & Kohli, M (Eds), Family, kinship and state in contemporary Europe Vol 3: Perspectives on theory and policy. Campus, Frankfurt, 15–30.
  • Heady, P, Gruber, S & Ou, Z, 2010. Family, kindred and marriage. In Heady, P & Kohli, M (Eds), Family, kinship and state in contemporary Europe Vol 3: Perspectives on theory and policy. Campus, Frankfurt, 31–70.
  • Hilgeman, C & Butts, CT, 2009. Women's employment and fertility: A welfare regime paradox. Social Science Research 38, 103–117. doi: 10.1016/j.ssresearch.2008.08.005
  • Höllinger, F & Haller, M, 1990. Kinship and social networks in modern societies: A cross-cultural comparison among seven nations. European Sociological Review 6(2), 103–124.
  • Huang. T & Xie, Z, 2013. Population and economic growth: A simultaneous equation perspective. Applied Economics 45(27), 3820–3826. doi: 10.1080/00036846.2012.734596
  • Isengard, B, 2013. ‘The apple doesn't live far from the tree’: Living distances between parents and their adult children in Europe. Comparative Population Studies – Zeitschrift für Bevölkerungswissenschaft 38(2), 237–262.
  • Jappens, M & Van Bavel, J, 2012. Regional family norms and child care by grandparents in Europe. Demographic Research 27(4), 85–120. doi: 10.4054/DemRes.2012.27.4
  • Johnson, NE & Stokes, CS, 1976. Family size in successive generations: The effects of birth order, intergenerational change in lifestyle, and familial satisfaction. Demography 13(2), 175–187. doi: 10.2307/2060799
  • Keim, S, 2011. Social networks and family formation processes. VS-Verlag, Wiesbaden.
  • Klevmarker, A, Swensson, B & Hesselius, P, 2005. The SHARE sampling procedures and calibrated design weights. In Boersch-Supan, A & Juerges, H (Eds.), The survey of health, aging and retirement in Europe – methodology. Research Institute for the Economics of Aging, Mannheim, 32–33.
  • Kohler, HP, Behrman, JR & Watkins, SC, 2001. The density of social networks and fertility decisions: Evidence from South Nyanza District, Kenya. Demography 38(1), 43–58. doi: 10.1353/dem.2001.0005
  • Kohler, HP, Rodgers, JL, Miller, WB, Skytthe, A & Christensen, K, 2005. Bio-social determinants of fertility. International Journal of Andrology 29, 46–53. doi: 10.1111/j.1365-2605.2005.00606.x
  • Kohli, M, Künemund, H & Lüdicke, J, 2005. Family structure, proximity and contact. In Börsch-Supan, A, Brugiavini, A, Jürges, H, Mackenback, J, Siegrist, J & Weber, G (Eds), Health, aging and retirement in Europe: First results from SHARE. Research Institute for the Economics of Aging, Mannheim, 166–173.
  • Kok, J, 2009. Family systems as frameworks for understanding variation in extra marital births, Europe 1900–2000. Romanian Journal of Population Studies (Supplement/2009), 13–38.
  • Lawson, DW & Mace, R, 2011. Parental investment and the optimization of human family size. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society 366, 333–343. doi: 10.1098/rstb.2010.0297
  • Lesthaeghe, R & Neels, K, 2002. From the first to the second demographic transition: An interpretation of the spatial continuity of demographic innovation in France, Belgium and Switzerland. European Journal of Population 18, 325–60. doi: 10.1023/A:1021125800070
  • Lewbel, A, 1997. Constructing instruments for regressions with measurement error when no additional data are available, with an application to patents and R&D. Econometrica 65(5), 1201–1213. doi: 10.2307/2171884
  • Lewbel, A, 2012. Using heteroscedasticity to identify and estimate mismeasured and endogenous regressor models. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 30(1), 67–80. doi: 10.1080/07350015.2012.643126
  • Litwak, E & Kulis, S, 1987. Technology, proximity, and measures of kin support. Journal of Marriage and the Family 49(3), 649–661. doi: 10.2307/352210
  • Livi-Bacci, M, 2001. Too few children and too much family. Daedalus 130(3), 139–155.
  • Lyngstad, TH & Prskawetz, A, 2010. Do siblings’ fertility decisions influence each other? Demography 47(4), 923–934. doi: 10.1007/BF03213733
  • Macfarlane, A, 1981. Demographic structures and cultural regions in Europe. Cambridge Anthropology 6(1 & 2), 1–17.
  • Madhavan, S, Adams, A & Simon, D, 2003. Women's networks and the social world of fertility behavior. International Family Planning Perspectives 29(2), 58–68. doi: 10.2307/3181059
  • Mason, KO, 2001. Gender and family systems in the fertility transition. Population and Development Review 27 (Supplement: Global Fertility Transition), 160–176.
  • Micheli, GA, 2005. Kinship, family and social network: The anthropological embedment of fertility change in Southern Europe. In Dalla Zuanna, G & Micheli, GA (Eds), Strong family and low fertility: A paradox? Kluwer Academic Publishers, New York, Boston, Dordrecht, London, Moscow, 77–104.
  • Micheli, GA, 2012. Two strong families in southern Europe? Re-examining the geography of kinship regimes stemming from the reciprocity mechanisms between generations. European Journal of Population 28, 17–38. doi: 10.1007/s10680-011-9245-y
  • Mönkediek, B & Bras, H, 2014. Strong and weak family ties revisited: reconsidering European family structures from a network perspective. The History of the Family 19(2), 235–259. doi: 10.1080/1081602X.2014.897246
  • Montgomery, MR & Casterline, JB, 1996. Social influence, social learning and new models of fertility. Population and Development Review 22 (Supplement: Fertility in the United States: New Patterns, New Theories), 151–175.
  • Moore, G, 1990. Structural determinants of men's and women's personal networks. American Sociological Review 55(5), 726–735. doi: 10.2307/2095868
  • Newson, L, 2009. Cultural versus reproductive success: Why does economic development bring new tradeoffs? American Journal of Human Biology 21, 464–471. doi: 10.1002/ajhb.20925
  • Newson, L & Richardson, PJ, 2009. Why do people become modern? A Darwinian explanation. Population and Development Review 35(1), 117–158. doi: 10.1111/j.1728-4457.2009.00263.x
  • Newson, L, Postmes, T, Lea, SEG & Webley, P, 2005. Why are modern families small? Toward an evolutionary and cultural explanation for the demographic transition. Personality and Social Psychology Review 9(4), 360–375. doi: 10.1207/s15327957pspr0904_5
  • Newson, L, Postmes, T, Lea, SEG, Webley, P, Richerson, PJ & Mcelreath, R, 2007. Influences on communication about reproduction: the cultural evolution of low fertility. Evolution and Human Behavior 28, 199–210. doi: 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2007.01.003
  • Park, S & Gupta, S, 2012. Handling endogenous regressors by joint estimation using copulas. Marketing Science 31(4), 567–586. doi: 10.1287/mksc.1120.0718
  • Peréz, MD & Livi-Bacci, M, 1992. Fertility in Italy and Spain: The lowest in the world. Family Planning Perspectives 24(4), 162–167, 171. doi: 10.2307/2136019
  • Reher, DS, 1998. Family ties in Western Europe: Persistent contrasts. Population and Development Review 24(2), 203–234. doi: 10.2307/2807972
  • Rigobon, R, 2003. Identification through heteroskedasticity. Review of Economics and Statistics 85(4), 777–792. doi: 10.1162/003465303772815727
  • Rigobon, R & Rodrik, D, 2005. Rule of law, democracy, openness, and income. Economics of Transition 13 (3), 533–564. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0351.2005.00226.x
  • Salamon, S, 1977. Family bounds and friendship bonds: Japan and West Germany. Journal of Marriage and Family 39(4), 807–820. doi: 10.2307/350484
  • Santarelli, E & Cottone, F, 2009. Leaving home, family support and intergenerational ties in Italy: Some regional differences. Demographic Research 21(1), 1–22. doi: 10.4054/DemRes.2009.21.1
  • Sear, R & Coall, D, 2011. How much does family matter? Cooperative breeding and the demographic transition. Population and Development Review 37, 81–112. doi: 10.1111/j.1728-4457.2011.00379.x
  • Sear, R, Mace, R & McGregor, AI, 2003. The effects of kin on female fertility in rural Gambia. Evolution and Human Behavior 24(1), 25–42. doi: 10.1016/S1090-5138(02)00105-8
  • Shavit, Y & Pierce, JL, 1991. Sibship size and educational attainment in nuclear and extended families: Arabs and Jews in Israel. American Sociological Review 56(3), 321–330. doi: 10.2307/2096107
  • Skinner, GW, 1997. Family systems and demographic processes. In Kertzer, DI & Fricke, T (Eds), Anthropological demography: Toward a new synthesis. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 53–95.
  • Steelman, LC, Powell, B, Werum, R. & Carter, S, 2002. Reconsidering the effects of sibling configuration: Recent advances and challenges. Annual Review of Sociology 28, 243–269. doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.28.111301.093304
  • Steenhof, L & Liefbroer, AC, 2008. Intergenerational transmission of age at first birth in the Netherlands for birth cohorts born between 1935 and 1984: Evidence from municipal registers. Population Studies 62(1), 69–84. doi: 10.1080/00324720701788616
  • Stegmueller, D, 2013. How many countries for multilevel modeling? A comparison of frequentist and Bayesian approaches. American Journal of Political Science 57(3), 748–761. doi: 10.1111/ajps.12001
  • Therborn, G, 2004. Between sex and power: Family in the world, 1900–2000. Routledge, London.
  • Todd, E, 1990. L'invention de l'Europe. Seuil, Paris.
  • Tymicki, K, 2004. Kin influence on female reproductive behavior: The evidence from reconstitution of the Bejsce parish registers, 18th to 20th centuries, Poland. American Journal of Human Biology 16, 508–522. doi: 10.1002/ajhb.20059
  • Tymicki, K, 2008. When do kinsmen really help? Examination of cohort and parity-specific kin effects on fertility behavior. The case of Bejsce parish register reconstitution study, 17th–20th centuries, Poland. In Bengtsson, T & Mineau, GP (Eds), Kinship and demographic behavior in the past. Springer, Dordrecht, 135–154.
  • Van Bavel, J, 2004. Deliberate birth spacing before the fertility transition in Europe: Evidence from nineteenth-century Belgium. Population Studies: A Journal of Demography 58(1), 95–107. doi: 10.1080/0032472032000167706
  • Van Bavel, J & Kok, J, 2009. Social control and the intergenerational transmission of age at marriage in rural Holland, 1850–1940. Population 64(2), 343–360.
  • Van Bavel, J, Moreels, S, Van de Putte, B & Matthijs, K, 2011. Family size and intergenerational social mobility during the fertility transition: Evidence of resource dilution from the city of Antwerp in nineteenth century Belgium. Demographic Research 24(14), 313–344. doi: 10.4054/DemRes.2011.24.14
  • Veleti, K, 2001. Family structure and its effective influence on fertility. Journal of Human Ecology 12(5), 387–390.
  • Viazzo, PP, 2010a. Macro-regional differences in European kinship culture. In Heady, P & Kohli, M (Eds), Family, kinship and state in contemporary Europe Vol 3: Perspectives on theory and policy. Campus, Frankfurt, 271–294.
  • Viazzo, PP, 2010b. Family, kinship and welfare provision in Europe, past and present: Commonalities and divergences. Continuity and Change 25(1), 137–159. doi: 10.1017/S0268416010000020
  • Viazzo, PP & Zanotelli, F, 2010. Welfare as moral obligation: changing patterns of family support in Italy and the Mediterranean. In Grandits, H (Ed), Family, kinship and state in contemporary Europe. The Century of Welfare: Eight Countries. Campus, Frankfurt, 47–92.
  • Vignoli, D, Rinesi, F & Mussino, E, 2013. A home to plan the first child? Fertility intentions and housing conditions in Italy. Population, Space and Place 19, 60–71. doi: 10.1002/psp.1716
  • Widmer, ED & Jallinoja, R, 2008. Afterthoughts. In Widmer, ED & Jallinoja, R (Eds), Beyond the nuclear family: Families in a configurational perspective. Peter Lang, Bern, Berlin, Brussels, 397–401.
  • Yorburg, B, 1975. The nuclear and the extended family: An area of conceptual confusion. Journal of Comparative Family Studies 6(1), 5–14.

APPENDIX 1

Table A1: Cases per NUTS 2 region*

*Note: The first column shows the number of cases per NUTS regions. The second column shows the number of cases included in the regression analysis per NUTS region. For Germany information was only available on NUTS 1 levels. For Denmark, where the information was available on NUTS3 levels, I aggregated regions into three higher clusters (into north-west, south and east Denmark).
Table A1: Cases per NUTS 2 region*

APPENDIX 2

Explanation of the applied instrumental variables (IV) approach

Instrumental variables (IV) regression is applicable when regressors are endogenous or mis-measured. So far, several different IV methods have been developed (Ebbes et al. Citation2009; Park & Gupta Citation2012, 568; Lewbel Citation2012, 67). One of these is the instrument free Lewbel's approach (LA) (Lewbel Citation1997, 2012). This approach has the advantage that it does not require any variables (instruments) replacing any endogenous covariates. This solves the problem of fulfilling the criteria for instruments (1) being exogenous, (2) having enough explanatory power to explain the endogenous variable, and (3) not being directly related to the dependent variable (Ebbes et al. Citation2009, 448–449). In the LA, instruments are generated from the data by multiplying the heteroscedastic error terms from a first stage regression with the subset of mean centred exogenous regressors (Z) (Lewbel Citation2012, 73; Brown Citation2014, 38). These regressors can be any set of exogenous covariates so that no information outside the model is needed. In this context, the model relies on the assumptions that (Lewbel Citation2012, 69, 72):

,

while a simultaneous equation system additionally requires that

for the model to be identified.

In this study we assume that unobserved regional family systems influence people's fertility and their observed social relationships which form our network indicators. In doing so I reduce the model's assumptions to an unobserved single factor model, assuming that (1) there are variables which are not correlated with the error terms, (2) the error term is heteroscedastic and (3) the covariance between the subset of regressors (Z) and the heteroscedastic error is zero (Lewbel Citation2012, 77). While assumption (1) requires the variables to be exogenous, we can test for assumption (2) using the Breusch-Pagan test. Assumption (3) can be tested by testing the exclusion restriction of the generated instruments. If the generated instruments do not satisfy the covariance restriction then they fail the exclusion restriction tests (Emran & Shilpi Citation2012, 1137). Yet Lewbel (Citation2012) demonstrates that, even if the third assumption is not met, the model can be used to identify the internal bounds of the model parameters for cases in which the covariance is relatively small (compared to the heteroscedasticity in the error terms; Lewbel Citation2012, 74). Unfortunately, estimates derived from Lewbel's (Citation2012, 67) approach are less reliable than the results of traditional IV models. But the approach can be augmented by combining it with traditional instruments found in the dataset; this increases its estimation efficiency (2012, 77).

The performance of the LA has been demonstrated by previous research in economics and health economics (Lewbel Citation1997, Citation2012; Ebbes et al. Citation2009; Emran & Shilpi Citation2012; Denny & Oppedisano Citation2013; Huang & Xie Citation2013; for an overview see Brown Citation2014, 39). To estimate the LA models and test their underlying assumptions, we use the ivreg2 h Stata-module, developed by Baum and Schaffer (Citation2012). For model estimation we use the LIML estimator, which performs well under finite sample conditions (Baum et al. Citation2007: 478). Testing the model assumptions, we need to be sure that there is a subset of exogenous variables (Z) in our model. Among other factors, we include country dummies and respondents’ birth cohort to explain respondents’ fertility. These variables are clearly exogenous with respect to people's fertility and the structure of their social relationships. Moreover, these variables can be assumed to give rise to the heteroscedasticity in the data. Thus, we can accept the first model's assumption as being fulfilled. Applying the Breusch-Pagan test to a simplified OLS version of our model, which includes only our covariates, suggests that there is enough heteroscedasticity in the error term to fulfil the second model's requirement (Breusch-Pagan-Test: chi² = 1,229.59; P = 0.000). Finally, to test the exclusion restriction we apply the Hansen J test and report its results for each model at the end of the regression tables. Testing the null-hypothesis that the included instruments are valid, the observed strong rejection of null-hypothesis in most of our models suggests that the covariance restriction is fulfilled and the LA can be applied.