1,111
Views
4
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Short Article

Firm subsidies in Central and Eastern Europe and Central Asia: is there urban bias?

Pages 49-56 | Received 20 May 2016, Accepted 06 Mar 2017, Published online: 03 Apr 2017

Abstract

Regional disparities exist due to the uneven impact of economic development. The World Bank’s World Development Report (2009) advocates that attempts to spread out economic activity will undermine growth. This study finds that policy-makers in Central and Eastern Europe and Central Asia favour subsidizing firms in less urbanized locations. However, innovation market outcomes would probably be higher if there was an urban bias in subsidy distribution.

Jel Classification Codes:

Introduction

Economic development is not evenly spread. The World Bank’s (Citation2009) World Development Report: Reshaping Economic Geography. states the challenge for governments is to allow, and even encourage, ‘unbalanced’ economic growth and attempts to spread out economic activity will undermine national growth. The underlying theoretical ideas in the WDR for development are cemented in new economic geography theory (NEG). In summary, the central argument of the report is for policy-makers to take a space-blind approach where growing cities are critical for development (Barca, McCann, & Rodríguez-Pose, Citation2012). However, there are other reports that advocate for place-based interventions to tackle regional disparities. The Barca Report (Barca, 2009) for instance, based on two influential Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (Citation2009a, Citation2009b) reports, argues for developed European Union countries that placed-based policies and the specificity of the wider regional and local context of institutional, cultural and social characteristics matters for development policy. Policies should focus on tackling underutilized resources and social exclusion in peripheral regions (Barca, 2009).

While both reports are focused on regions and countries other than those studied in this paper, their conceptual catalysts propose an interesting dilemma for policy-makers. That is, should policy-makers follow a space-blind approach and abandon lagging rural areas in favour of growing urban areas or should they follow a place-based approach and try to exploit the unused potential of peripheral regions? Or alternatively, by blending policy ideas from both reports, policy-makers may support both urban and rural areas. The primary objective of this study is to examine what approach policy-makers are currently taking in Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) and Central Asian economies.

This study examines whether policy-makers subsidize firms in urban or rural areas. Following this, it explores what are the subsidy–firm performance outcomes. Particular interest is attributed to the firm-performance outcomes for firms located across areas with different levels of urbanization. The focus here is on developing and under-developing countries which are the primary countries of concern for the WDR (2009). The study employs an endogenous treatment-effects model using data from the Business Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey (BEEPS).

Literature Review

Increasing returns and positive external economies generated by urban growth play a pivotal role in shaping economic development (Krugman, Citation1991). Firms benefit from urbanization and/or localization externalities which occur in larger cities (Romer, Citation1986). Larger cities have ‘more’ resources such as access to larger labour pools, better infrastructure, access to better universities, schools, services and so forth. Being located in a more concentrated area also creates more interaction and experiences between agents which enable individuals to learn, develop and accumulate more skills at a faster pace (Glaeser, Citation1998). A large number of firms in the same industry benefit from cluster effects (Porter, Citation1990), from sharing pooled specialized labour and market information with customers, competitors and suppliers. However, urban areas can also suffer from agglomeration diseconomies and local institutional weaknesses are also evident in densely populated and core regions (McCann & Ortega-Argilés, Citation2013).

Less urbanized peripheral regions can have weakly developed support organizations and a lack of dynamic clusters (Tödtling & Trippl, Citation2005), and have place disadvantages that cities do not have such as poor access to the technological frontier, critical markets and skilled labour (Bergström, Citation2000). As a result, economic performance is often uneven throughout national landscapes. Hirschman (Citation1957) identified that one of the problems associated with economic growth is a dualism effect where there is uneven development of industry throughout geographical areas within a country.

In terms of CEE and Central Asian economies, the most influential recent report on development strategies is arguably the World Bank’s World Development Report (2009). The report has received much criticism particularly from economic geographers primarily in terms of its treatment of institutions, urban bias and in the report’s recommendation of spatially blind policies (Rodríguez-Pose, Citation2010). The Barca Report (Barca, 2009) on the reform of European Cohesion Policy and the OECD (Citation2009a) report How Regions Grow advocate that development policy needs to be place-based and connected to local institutional conditions. Essentially, these key international reports are advocating contrasting approaches to the development policy prescribed in the WDR. However, it is unclear if policy-makers in CEE and Central Asian economies are following the approach advocated by the World Bank. Would following the advice of the World Bank lead to improved regional outcomes?

Methodology and Data

A two-step model is employed to examine, firstly, the location of recipient firms (whilst controlling for other factors) and, secondly, the subsidy–performance outcomes at different levels of urbanization. Firms may be subsidized by policy-makers based on the expected outcomes the intervention will achieve. Therefore, firm performance and the allocation of subsidies are potentially simultaneously related. This simultaneity creates a selection bias (Crowley & McCann, Citation2015) as firms that receive subsidies are not chosen at random. Hence, controlling for subsidies by measuring for effects from independent variables is complicated by the fact that subsidy allocation is also a function of firm performance. Given this logic, there is some unobservable factor that affects both assignment to treatment (subsidies in this case) and the potential outcome (STATACORP, Citation2015). Hence, to control for this unobservable factor in both the treatment and potential outcome, an endogenous treatment-effects model is chosen for the estimation, which produces the treatment-effects models outlined in equations (Equation1) to (Equation6):(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

where, for firm i, is the potential outcome of receiving a subsidy; Yi0 is the potential outcome when the subsidy is not received; Ti is the observed binary treatment of being a particular firm that fits the government’s strategy for intervention; and is the observed outcome. and Yi1 are determined by its expected value conditional on a set of determinants Xi and an error term ei0 . The determinants for Xi include whether the firm is research and development (R&D) active, firm size, education and training of employees within the firm, industry type, age of the firm, age and domestic interaction variable (infant domestic firm), location indicator, main market indicator, domestic firm, multiplant firm indicator and country dummies. The subsidy treatment is given by its expectation conditional on a set of determinants . The determinants of are outlined in Table . Equation (Equation6) includes endogeneity to the estimation, where the unobservables between outcome and treatment are correlated. Using this methodology, the potential-outcome means (POMs) and average treatment effects (ATE) are estimated. See STATACORP (Citation2015) for more information on the empirical approach behind these estimations.

Table 1. Variables and mean estimates.

The data used for this study stem from the fifth Business Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey (BEEPS). BEEPS provides firm-level data on a broad range of issues about the business environment and performance of firms, including business–government relations, firm financing, labour, infrastructure, informal payments and corruption, and other topics such as training and innovation (Bank, Citation2014). There are 6,710 observations used for this analysis from 18 countries,Footnote1 where government intervention is more prevalent. BEEPS is particularly useful for investigating the type of questions being studied in this paper as it is rich in firm-performance indicators, urbanization location indicators, internal-firm indicators and business geographic–environment indicators. A description and mean statistics of the variables are outline in Table . Almost 12% of the firms sampled received government subsidies.Footnote2 A total of 37% of firms introduced a new-to-firm or new-to-market innovation. A total of 37% and 74% of firms experienced productivityFootnote3 and employment growth, respectively. The results are presented and discussed in the next section.

Results

From the results shown in Table , the targeted firms are in less urbanized areas, are large, high-tech, manufacturing, older, invest in employee training and sell their products nationally or internationally. Clearly, there is subsidy bias towards less urbanized regions. This bias is contrary to the advice outlined in WDR (2009). Balanced regional development appears to be a significant factor for policy-makers in CEE and Central Asian economies. The other spatial implication of these results is that firms that operate in local markets are less likely to receive subsidy support. This suggests that the potential for firms to export and enter foreign markets may be a key driver of subsidy allocation decisions.

Table 2. What types of firms are more likely to receive subsidies (equation Equation3)?

The average treatment effects (ATE) (Table ) indicate that subsidies have a positive effect on firm innovation and employment growth outcomes. Evidently, subsidy intervention is having a positive effect and improving market outcomes, relative to the counterfactual of a world with no subsidies. From a regional development perspective, it is critical to identify if firm performance returns are higher for subsidized firms in more urbanized location vis-à-vis subsidized firms in more rural regional locations. Table presents the results for this analysis. Firms in less urbanized locations (relative to capital and city with populations over 1 million) are significantly less likely to innovate. Firms located in mid-sized cities (with a population between 50,000 and 250,000) are less likely to have employment growth, relative to the reference category. However, firms located in less urbanized locations are more productive.

Table 3. Firm performance average treatment effects (ATE) and potential outcome means (POMs).

Table 4. Performance returns for subsidized firms in less urbanized locations.

Conclusions

This study has identified a number of findings relevant for regional policy and development in CEE and Central Asian economies. The allocation bias to less urbanized areas may be motivated to counter unbalanced regional growth caused by market forces. Such an approach is inconsistent with the advice from the WDR (2009). Policy-makers in CEE and Central Asian economies may see a trade-off between efficiency and equity and are opting for rebalancing growth in emerging regions through subsidy bias. Perhaps such an approach may help lagging regions make productive use of their resources – resources which otherwise may be constrained if left to market and agglomeration forces (Farole, Rodríguez-Pose, & Storper, Citation2011; McCann & Ortega-Argilés, Citation2013). This is an approach that is more aligned with recommendations of the Barca Report (Barca, 2009).

What is clear for policy-makers in the context of regional development is that the likelihood of innovation returns is lower in less urbanized locations. However, efficiency gains for subsidized firms are greater in more rural locations. These results may seem counter-intuitive, but perhaps subsidies are offsetting the disadvantages of more isolated locations. Additionally, the paradox may be explained by product life cycle theory (PLC) (McCann, Citation2007). Subsidized firms in more urban areas may be more likely to product innovate because they are benefitting from urbanization and localization externality advantages, as described above under NEG theory, which are important for the earlier stages of the PLC. Firms in rural areas may be concentrating more of their efforts on being efficient as their products may be more standardized. Hence, firms located in rural areas may have better productivity but reduced capacities to product innovate. Further, the results suggest that if more urban firms were (counterfactual) subsidized at the expense of rural firms, innovation market outcomes would probably have been greater, which undermines long-term economic growth.

Of course, the analysis is not without its limitations. The study draws on data from across many CEE and Central Asian economies and, hence, the local implications of vertical firm subsidy targeting at a country level are lost. There are also potential limitations with the data as BEEPS V measures perceptions of the business environment which may influence how respondents answer firm-performance questions. Further, much of the criticism of the WDR was focused on the spatially blind institutional approach of the report. Future studies should focus on examining the importance of local institutions in supporting subsidy provision and outcomes.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.

Acknowledgment

I would like to thank Dr. Declan Jordan (UCC) for helpful comments on a previous draft of this paper and to participants at the 2016 annual conference of RSAI-BIS.

Notes

1. This sample is smaller than the original sample as the data from all countries were not used. This was primarily due to low subsidy allocations in some countries. In addition, not all firms answered all questions in the data for the countries used. In particular, this was the case for sales data. The countries included are Slovenia, Slovakia, Lithuania, Latvia, Hungary, Czech Republic, Estonia, Mongolia, Bosnia-Herzegovina, Moldova, Kazakhstan, Serbia, Romania, Poland, Russia, Turkey, Croatia and Bulgaria.

2. The data do not indicate what the subsidy was granted for.

3. Productivity is measured as the log of sales per worker. Sales data have been adjusted to purchasing power parities (PPP) across countries using world development indicators’ PPP conversion data from the World Bank. Growth is only measured as a binary variable that is either 1 if the firm experienced growth, and 0 otherwise. Using a measure of productivity, such as total factor productivity, would result in the loss of a substantial number of observations, and sales per worker is a widely used measure in the literature.

References

  • Bank, E.-W. (2014). Business environment and enterprise performance survey. In Enterprise Surveys. The World Bank. http://www.enterprisesurveys.org
  • Barca, F. (2009). An Agenda for a Reformed Cohesion Policy: A Place-Based Approach to Meeting European Union Challenges and Expectations. Independent report prepared at the request of the European Commissioner for Regional Policy, Danuta Hübner. Brussels: European Commission.
  • Barca, F., McCann, P., & Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2012). The case for regional development intervention: Place-based versus place-neutral approaches. Journal of regional science, 52, 134–152.10.1111/jors.2012.52.issue-1
  • Bergström, F. (2000). Capital subsidies and the performance of firms. Small Business Economics, 14, 183–193.10.1023/A:1008133217594
  • Crowley, F., & McCann, P. (2015). Innovation and productivity in Irish Firms. Spatial Economic Analysis, 10, 181–204.10.1080/17421772.2015.1023340
  • Farole, T., Rodríguez-Pose, A., & Storper, M. (2011). Cohesion policy in the European Union: Growth, geography, institutions. JCMS. Journal of Common Market Studies, 49, 1089–1111.10.1111/jcms.2011.49.issue-5
  • Glaeser, E. L. (1998). Are cities dying? Journal of Economic Perspectives , 12, 139–160.10.1257/jep.12.2.139
  • Hirschman, A. O. (1957). Investment policies and” dualism” in underdeveloped countries. The American Economic Review, 47, 550–570.
  • Krugman, P. R. (1991). Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of Political Economy, 99, 483–499.10.1086/261763
  • McCann, P. (2007). Sketching out a model of innovation, face-to-face interaction and economic geography. Spatial Economic Analysis, 2, 117–134.10.1080/17421770701346622
  • McCann, P., & Ortega-Argilés, R. (2013). Modern regional innovation policy. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 6, 187–216.10.1093/cjres/rst007
  • OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development). (2009a). How regions grow: Trends and analysis. Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.
  • OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development). (2009b). Regions matter: Economic recovery, innovation and sustainable growth. Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.
  • Porter, M. E. (1990). The competitive advantage of nations. New York, NY: Free Press.10.1007/978-1-349-11336-1
  • Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2010). Economic geographers and the limelight: Institutions and policy in the World Development Report 2009. Economic Geography, 86, 361–370.10.1111/ecge.2010.86.issue-4
  • Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. The Journal of Political Economy, 94, 1002–1037.10.1086/261420
  • STATACORP. (2015). Stata treatment-effects reference manual. Stata: Release 14. Statistical Software. College Station, TX: StataCorp LP.
  • Tödtling, F., & Trippl, M. (2005). One size fits all?: Towards a differentiated regional innovation policy approach. Research Policy, 34, 1203–1219.10.1016/j.respol.2005.01.018
  • World Bank. (2009). World development report 2009. Reshaping economic geography. Washington, DC: World Bank.