829
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Asymmetries in the capital structure speed of adjustment: The idiosyncratic case of the maritime industry

ORCID Icon, ORCID Icon &
Article: 2066764 | Received 11 Oct 2021, Accepted 09 Apr 2022, Published online: 27 Apr 2022

Abstract

This study investigates asymmetries in the capital structure speed of adjustment in the case of a capital-intensive industry. Employing a sample of globally listed maritime, manufacturing and services firms between 1995 and 2020, we estimate a regime-switching partial adjustment model, to test whether the capital structure speed of adjustment depends on a firm’s positioning relative to the target. After accounting for the fractional, bounded nature of leverage ratios using a DPF estimator we document that maritime firms exhibit a higher (lower) speed of adjustment when they lie below (above) their target. Our empirical findings suggest that this asymmetric behavior holds across industries but is more profound in maritime firms emphasizing this industry’s particularity.

JEL classification:

PUBLIC INTEREST STATEMENT

In this study, we focus on the financing decision, i.e., how much debt to take, of maritime firms. We test the validity of the Trade-Off theory which suggests that firms reach an optimal capital structure by balancing the benefits of debt against its disadvantages. The benefit of debt results from the associated interest payments which reduce taxable income and consequently the amount of taxes due; the disadvantage of debt stems from increased costs of financial distress (i.e., higher cost of capital). We find that maritime firms do move towards a target debt ratio although at a more moderate pace than firms in the services and manufacturing sectors. Our findings improve our understanding of financial decisions of maritime companies and highlight their distinctiveness, specifically, i) the absence tax advantage of debt is trivial due to sector-specific tax regimes and ii) the comparatively higher amount of debt of maritime firms that impedes their ability to adjust to back to the target debt ratio when deviating from above.

1. Introduction

The extant empirical and theoretical research on capital structure has flourished upon the economic foundation set by Modigliani and Miller (Citation1958). Their famous “irrelevance theorem” has brought under the spotlight the market frictions that render the capital structure decision value-relevant. One of the most prominent capital structure theories, the trade-off theory, suggests that firms balance the benefits of debt against its disadvantages. Increased leverage can benefit firms due to the resulting tax shield or the mitigation of agency costs of free cash flows. However, increased leverage can also magnify financial distress costs, agency costs of debt and hamper financial flexibility as borrowing capacity becomes exhausted. Thus, trade-off theory implies that firms have an optimal target leverage where firm value is maximized. A testable hypothesis regarding the latter is that if firms deviate from their target due to micro or macro-level leverage shocks, they are expected to revert to the target eventually. The relevant empirical research which explores the so-called capital structure speed of adjustment (SOA) provides noticeable empirical support to the trade-off theory. Specifically, several studies on national and international samples document a positive and economically significant SOA suggesting that firms do adjust back to target leverage (Drobetz et al. Citation2015; Alnori & Alqahtani, Citation2019; An et al., Citation2021; Elsas & Florysiak, Citation2015; Kannadhasan et al., Citation2018; Öztekin & Flannery, Citation2012; Vo et al., Citation2022). Moreover, the aforementioned studies document considerable heterogeneity in the SOA between countries with diverse institutional and legal characteristics and market efficiency. Moreover, a number of studies focus on, asymmetries in the speed of adjustment depending on whether the firm reverts to its target from a position above or below its optimal target, have been understudied. Such insight would be valuable in drawing an integrated framework of the dynamics of capital structure.

In the current study, we explore SOA asymmetries concentrating on the maritime industry motivated by its significance and distinct characteristics. The maritime sector plays a pivotal role in facilitating global trade, is highly pro-cyclical while exhibiting high leverage and asset risk, characteristics which often lead to divergent financial decisions (Ahrends et al., Citation2018; Drobetz et al., Citation2013). Moreover, it is common for maritime firms to pay taxes according to their tonnageFootnote1 (tonnage tax regimes) rather than paying tax on accounting profits. Additionally, maritime firms enjoy sector-specific tax incentives and favorable tax regimes that lead to a trivial effective tax rate for maritime firms. Therefore, the tax-shield motive which plays a central role in the Trade-Off Theory (S. Myers, Citation1984) seems irrelevant for maritime firms. Accordingly, we hypothesize that due to the absence of a tax shield motive, ceteris paribus, maritime firms are expected to face lower costs of deviating below their target and thus approach their target at a slower pace than firms in other industries. Moreover, the highly levered, financially constrained risk profile of maritime firms may lead to both significant higher cost of adjustment (thus lowering the SOA from a position above optimal leverage) and higher costs of financial distress (thus increasing the SOA from a position above optimal leverage). Considering, the discussion in this paragraph in this study we aim to answer the following empirical research question. Does the SOA of maritime firms depend on their position relative to their target and in this respect are there any significant differences vis-à-vis other industries? There is a limited number of studies that focus on capital structure dynamics in the maritime sector, however these do not focus on SOA asymmetries and sectoral differences (see, Drobetz et al. Citation2015) or focus solely on a single country sample of maritime companies (see Guo et al. Citation2020).

To address our research objective, we use a regime-switching approach motivated by Apergis (Citation2021) and Drobetz et al. (Citation2015). Specifically, we employ a regime-switching partial adjustment model that allows the SOA and the effect of target leverage determinants to differ depending on the firm’s positioning relative to the target. Such an approach suits the analysis of divergent behavior between two different states. In our case, we are interested in the divergent behavior of capital structure’s speed of adjustment above and below target leverage. Moreover, to account for the mechanical mean reversion due to the bounded nature of leverage ratios we employ the Elsas and Florysiak (Citation2015) DPF estimator. Also, we compare and contrast our findings from the maritime industry to those obtained from the service and manufacturing industries. Section 2 presents our methodology, section 3 the data, section 4 discusses the results and section 5 concludes.

2. Methodology

Our research initiative investigates asymmetries in SOA between firms resulting from their positioning above and below the optimal leverage. To identify a firm’s position against the target we proxy for a firm’s optimal leverage using the fitted values from regressing leverage on well-known capital structure determinants drawn from the extant literature (Drobetz et al., Citation2013; Rajan & Zingales, Citation1995). Specifically, we estimate Equationequation 1,

(1) Levit=aι+βitZit+νt+μi+eι,t(1)

Where Lev is a firm’s leverage ratio, α is a constant, Ζ is a vector of explanatory variables,νt,μi are time and year fixed effects, and e is the disturbance term. Our set of control variables includes Profitability, Tangibility, FirmSize, GrowhtOpportunities, FreeCashFlows and Dividends. in the Appendix, provides variable descriptions. We included Profitability, as according to the Trade-Off theory profitable firms are expected to be more levered to shield their income from taxes. Nevertheless, more profitable firms are expected to be less levered according to the Trade-Off theory as they can fund investment internally and thus are less likely to access debt financing. Tangibility and FirmSize may lower the costs of financial distress and lead to higher leverage. FreeCashFlows control for the presence of agency costs and the corresponding demand for debt as a disciplinary mechanism. We also, control for Dividends and Growth opportunities since all else equal, dividend paying firms and firms with substantial growth opportunities are more likely to require debt financing to secure investment capital.

After estimating EquationEquation 1,we compute the difference between the real leverage ratio and the optimal one (LevitLevˆit). If the difference is positive (negative) the firm lies above (below) target leverage. In each state, we assume that the SOA and the target leverage determinants vary. To capture divergent behavior in capital structure dynamics above and below target, we adapt the regime-switching partial adjustment model utilized by Drobetz et al. (Citation2015) who investigate heterogeneity in the speed of capital structure adjustment between different countries and macroeconomic states. Accordingly, we develop two separate models explain the adjustment process in each regime.

(2) LevitA=a1Levit1A+δ1ZitA+ν1t+μ1i+εitA(2)
(3) LevitB=a2Levit1B+δ2ZitB+ν2t+μ2i+εitB(3)

Where A (B) stands for the regime where the firm lies above (below) its target leverage. We then construct the dummy variables DA and DB which take the value of 1 if the firm falls in the respective regime and 0 otherwise and rewrite Equationequation 3 to.

(4) Levit=DA(a1Levit1+δ1Zit+νt+νi+εit)+DB(a2Levit1+δ1Zit+νt+ν1i+εit)(4)

where DA and DB are two regime dummy variables that equal to one if firm i is in the respective regime at time t and zero otherwise. Finally, we transform Equationequation 4 to reach the empirically testable model below.

(5) Levit=a1Levit1+(a2a1)Levit1DB+γ1Zit+(γ2γ1)ZitLevit1+νi+νi+εit(5)

In Equationequation 5, α1= 1-λˆA, α2= 1-λˆB where λA,λB is the speed of adjustment (SOA) in each regime. We estimate EquationEquation 5 using the DPF estimator constructed by Elsas and Florysiak (Citation2010) which accounts for the problem of mechanical mean reversion in SOA studies. This issue arises from the fractional nature of leverage ratios which are bounded between zero and one.

(6) Levi=0Levit0Levit0<Levit<11Levit1(6)

where Levit is the observed leverage, which is set to zero when it lower than zero, and set to one when it is above one. By doing so, the DPF estimator accounts for data errors considering that a normal leverage ratio lies between zero and one. The DPF estimator includes firm fixed effects to capture unobserved heterogeneity and time invariant characteristics.

(7) Levit=1λLevit1+δ1Zit+νt+μi+εit(7)

where,

(8) μi=α0+α1Levi0+E(Zi)α2+αi(8)

The unobserved firm fixed effect μi depends on the mean of the firm-specific variables E(Zi) and on the leverage in the first period Levi0. Tobit estimation follows a maximum likelihood approach. The DPF estimator is unbiased considering distribution misspecifications regarding the fixed effect (Elsas and Florysiak, 2010).

3. Data

As the current study focuses in global maritime firms, we draw firm-level data from Compustat Global. Our sample includes the global maritime (two-digit sic: 40–49), manufacturing (two-digit sic: 20–39) and service industry (two-digit sic: 70–89) for the period 1995–2020.Footnote2 For the maritime industry, we exclude the following firms i) shipyards and shipping ii) involved in passenger shipping, iii) drilling ships iv) supply vessels, and v) inland vessels. provides descriptive statistics for our variables per industry while , Appendix provides the variable definitions. shows that the average maritime firm is larger, more levered, has more tangible assets and generates more profits and free cash flows when compared to its manufacturing and services counterparts.

Table 1. Columns (1), (2) and (4) provide descriptive statistics per industry. Columns (3) and (5) provide t-tests for equal means between the maritime industry and the manufacturing and services industry respectively

4. Results

Table presents the results from estimating the regime-switching partial adjustment model in Equationequation 5. As a robustness test, we use two measures of leverage, namely book leverage and market leverage. Results support the economic relevance of the trade-off theory as the coefficient of the lagged leverage variable is positive across all industries suggesting that firms do have a target leverage ratio. This is in line with the Trade-Off Theory (S. Myers, Citation1984) and earlier empirical studies (Drobetz et al. Citation2015; Alnori & Alqahtani, Citation2019; An et al., Citation2021; Elsas & Florysiak, Citation2015; Kannadhasan et al., Citation2018; Öztekin & Flannery, Citation2012; Vo et al., Citation2022). Moreover, our findings show asymmetries between the two regimes (above and below target) for both SOA and the effect of target leverage determinants as the relevant interaction terms are statistically significant. For the three industries under consideration, we also compute the SOA in each regime and the half-life of a leverage shock (computed as log(0,5)/log(1-λ) where λ is the respective SOA. We present these in Table .

Table 2. Results from estimating the regime-switching partial adjustment model in Equationeq. 5 using the DPF estimator

Table 3. Results for the speed of adjustment (SOA) and half-life (in years) in each regime

Results show significant asymmetries in the SOA across industries. It appears that all firms approach target leverage faster from below than from above. This highlights a cost of adjustment differential since it would be less costly for the latter firm to issue debt and lever up than for the former to issue equity and un-lever. The maritime industry exhibits the slowest SOA across industries both from above and below. The slower approach from below is likely to reflect lower costs of deviation below the target due to the absence of tax shields. Moreover, a slower SOA from above suggests (see ) that the aforementioned cost of adjustment is comparatively higher than the cost of deviation due to the high-leverage profile nature of maritime firms. This characteristic is likely to increase equity financing and thus impede readjustments to target leverage.

To provide further robustness in our findings, we need to ensure that maritime companies and non-maritime companies in service and manufacturing share similar characteristics. In our baseline model we control for a rich set of firm characteristics. Nevertheless, as a robustness test in our findings we match a maritime to a non-maritime firm based on firm size and year by employing the Coarsened Exact Matching (CEM) procedure (Iacus et al., Citation2012). Our estimates considering speed of adjustment (SOA), remain in the same direction as in the baseline model. These results are reported in Table .

Table 4. Robustness test, counterparts-matched sample according to firm size and year

Our findings support S.C. Myers (Citation2001) who argues that capital structure theories are not general and thus testing them using large samples of dissimilar firms may mask considerable heterogeneity. Thus, stratification of firms into subsamples is a more suitable approach to test these theories.

5. Conclusion

This study explores the capital structure dynamics of globally listed maritime companies. First our results that maritime companies do move towards a target capital structure although at a more moderate pace than firms in the services and manufacturing sectors. Moreover, results showcase that maritime firms exhibit a higher (lower) speed of adjustment when they lie below (above) their target. This asymmetry is present in both the manufacturing and the services industry. Nevertheless, our findings are more profound in the maritime industry consistent with the notion that maritime firms face lower costs of deviating below the target due to their distinct taxation and the resulting absence of a tax shield. Moreover, although deviating above the target is likely to significantly raise costs of financial distress it appears that the corresponding cost of adjustment is comparatively higher due to the high-levered and financial constraint nature of maritime firms. This study provides further insight into the dynamics of capital structure. It contributes to the literature by highlighting sectoral asymmetries in the capital structure speed of adjustment which emphasize the distinctiveness of the maritime industry. From a research perspective, our findings support the contention of S.C. Myers (Citation2001) who warrants caution on the use of large cross-industry samples which estimate a single coefficient. Such estimations may not be as informative since they may conceal divergent behavior. The policy implication that stems from the results is that policy makers and financiers need to acknowledge that capital structure dynamics are not stable over time or across industries. Therefore, it may be the case that government policies lending policies of financiers may need to vary across industries as well, to match the distinct traits of each sector. We acknowledge that our results due to research design are applicable to the universe of maritime listed firms. An interesting avenue for further research would be to investigate, compare and contrast the capital structure dynamics of private versus listed maritime firms.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Additional information

Funding

The authors received no direct funding for this research.

Notes on contributors

Ioannis Chasiotis

Ioannis Chasiotis is Adjunct Lecturer at the University of the Peloponnese, Greece. He holds a PhD in Finance and Accounting from Durham University Business School, UK. His research interests and output focus on capital structure, payout policy, capital investment and corporate governance.

Dimitrios Konstantios

Dimitrios Konstantios is Adjunct Lecturer at the University of Piraeus, Greece. He holds a PhD in Finance from the University of Piraeus. His current research lies in studying the relationship between innovation and finance. Moreover, his published work is in the area of Corporate Finance.

Vassilios-Christos Naoum

Vassilios-Christos Naoum is an Assistant Professor at the University of Piraeus. His main areas of research include Financial Accounting (Cash flows, Persistence, Earnings Management), Management Accounting (Cost Behaviour) και Intangibles (Intellectual Capital, Organization Capital). Vasilios-Christos has published in journals such as the European Accounting Review, Management Accounting Research, International Journal of Finance and Economics.

Notes

1. See PricewaterhouseCoopers (Citation2009) for a comprehensive guide on maritime tax regimes.

2. The Compustat Global Database starts in 1987, however a lot of observations are missing before 1995.

3. Author’s calculations using the Compustat Global securities. Market value of equity has been calculated as the stock price (year-end) multiplied by the number of common shares outstanding.

References

  • Ahrends, Μ., Drobetz, W., & Nomikos, N. K. (2018). Corporate cash holdings in the shipping industry. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 112, 107–12. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2017.10.016
  • Alnori, F., & Alqahtani, F. (2019). Capital structure and speed of adjustment in non-financial firms: Does sharia compliance matter? Evidence from Saudi Arabia. Emerging Markets Review, 39, 50–67. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ememar.2019.03.008
  • An, Z., Chen, C., Li, D., & Yin, C. (2021). Foreign institutional ownership and the speed of leverage adjustment: International evidence. Journal of Corporate Finance, 68, 101966. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2021.101966
  • Apergis, N. (2021). The role of housing market in the effectiveness of monetary policy over the Covid-19 era. Economics Letters, 200, 109749. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2021.109749
  • Drobetz, W., Gounopoulos, D., Merikas, A. G., & Schröder, H. (2013). Capital structure decisions of globally-listed shipping companies. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 52, 49–76. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2012.11.008
  • Drobetz, W., Schilling, D. C., & Schröder, H. (2015). Heterogeneity in the speed of capital structure adjustment across countries and over the business cycle. European Financial Management, 21(5), 936–973. https://doi.org/10.1111/eufm.12048
  • Elsas, R., & Florysiak, D. (2015). Dynamic capital structure adjustment and the impact of fractional dependent variables. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 50(5), 1105–1133. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022109015000496
  • Elsas, R., & Florysiak, D. (2015). Dynamic Capital Structure Adjustment and the Impact of Fractional Dependent Variables. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 50(5), 1105–1133.
  • Guo, X., Liang, P. and Xie, Z. (2020). Executive Stock Ownership, Dynamic Adjustment of Capital Structure and Corporate Performance: Evidence from Chinese Listed Marine Industry Companies. Journal of Coastal Research, 106(SI), 300–304. https://doi.org/10.2112/SI106-070.1
  • Iacus, S. M., King, G., & Porro, G. (2012). Causal inference without balance checking: Coarsened exact matching. Political Analysis, 20(1), 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1093/pan/mpr013
  • Kannadhasan, M., Thakur, B. P. S., Gupta, C. P., Charan, P., & McMillan, D. (2018). Testing capital structure theories using error correction models: Evidence from China, India, and South Africa. Cogent Economics & Finance, 6(1), 1–19. https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2018.1443369
  • Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. The American Economic Review, 48(3), 261–297. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1809766
  • Myers, S. (1984). The capital structure puzzle. The Journal of Finance, 39(3), 575–592. https://doi.org/10.2307/2327916
  • Myers, S. C. (2001). Capital structure. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(2), 81–102. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.15.2.81
  • Öztekin, Ö., & Flannery, M. J. (2012). Institutional determinants of capital structure adjustment speeds. Journal of Financial Economics, 103(1), 88–112. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2011.08.014
  • PricewaterhouseCoopers. (2009). Choosing a profitable course around the globe: corporate taxation of the global shipping industry. from https://www.pwc.com/gr/en/publications/assets/choosing-course2015.pdf
  • Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (1995). What do we know about capital structure? Some evidence from international data. The Journal of Finance, 50(5), 1421–1460. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1995.tb05184.x
  • Richardson, S. (2006). Over-investment of free cash flow. Review of Accounting Studies, 11, 159–189. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-006-9012-1
  • Vo, T. A., Mazur, M., & Thai, A. (2022). The impact of COVID-19 economic crisis on the speed of adjustment toward target leverage ratio: An international analysis. Finance Research Letters, 45, 102157. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2021.102157

Appendix

Table A1. Variable definitions