1,850
Views
24
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Original Articles

Suspending vetoes: how the euro countries achieved unanimity in the fiscal compact

REFERENCES

  • Achen, C. (2006a) ‘Institutional realism and bargaining models’, in R. Thomson, F. Stokman, C. Achen and T. König (eds), The European Union Decides, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 86–123.
  • Achen, C. (2006b) ‘Evaluating political decision-making models’, in R. Thomson, F. Stokman, C. Achen and T. König (eds), The European Union Decides, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 264–98.
  • Aspinwall, M. (2007) ‘Government preferences on European integration: an empirical test of five theories’, British Journal of Political Science 37: 89–114. doi: 10.1017/S0007123407000051
  • Bailer, S. and Schneider, G. (2006) ‘Nash versus Schelling? The importance of constraints in legislative decision-making’, in R. Thomson, F. Stokman, C. Achen and T. König (eds), The European Union Decides, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 153–77.
  • Bueno de Mesquita, B. (1994) ‘Political forecasting: an expected utility model’, in B. Bueno de Mesquita, and F. Stokman. (eds), European Community Decision Making: Models, Applications and Comparisons, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, pp. 71–104.
  • Cini, M. (1996) The European Commission: Leadership, Organization and Culture in the EU Administration, Manchester: Manchester University Press.
  • Cooter, B. and Ginsburg, T. (2003). ‘Leximetrics: why the same laws are longer in some countries than in others’, Working Paper No.03-012, June, University of Illinois, College of Law.
  • Crombez, C. (1996) ‘Legislative procedures in the European Community’, British Journal of Political Science 26: 199–228. doi: 10.1017/S0007123400000429
  • Crombez, C. (1997) ‘The co-decision procedure in the European Union’, Legislative Studies Quarterly 22: 97–119. doi: 10.2307/440293
  • Crombez, C. and Hix, S. (2011) ‘Treaty reform and the Commission's appointment and policy-making role in the European Union’, European Union Politics 12(3): 291–314. doi: 10.1177/1465116511409601
  • Dimitrova, A. and Steunenberg, B. (2000) ‘The search for convergence of national policies in the European Union: an impossible quest?’, European Union Politics 1(2): 201–26. doi: 10.1177/1465116500001002003
  • Diver, C.S. (1983) ‘The optimal precision of administrative rules’, Yale Law Journal 93(1): 65–109. doi: 10.2307/796245
  • Diver, C.S. (1989) ‘Regulatory precision’, in K. Hawkins, and J. Thomas (eds), Making Regulatory Policy, Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press, pp. 199–232.
  • Economist (2011) ‘The euro crisis. One problem, two visions (part I)’, available at http://www.economist.com/blogs/charlemagne/2011/12/euro-crisis (accessed 12 June 2013).
  • Ehrlich, I. and Posner R. (1974) ‘An economic analysis of legal rulemaking’, Journal of Legal Studies 3(2): 257–86. doi: 10.1086/467515
  • Elgström, O. and Jönsson, C. (2000) ‘Negotiation in the European Union: bargaining or problem-solving?’, Journal of European Public Policy 7(5) 684–704. doi: 10.1080/13501760010014902
  • Falkner, G. (2011) The EU's Decision Traps: Comparing Policies, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Forster, A. (1998) ‘Britain and the negotiation of the Maastricht Treaty: a critique of liberal intergovernmentalism’, Journal of Common Market Studies 36(3): 347–67.
  • Frieden, J. (1992) ‘European monetary union: a political economy perspective’, Paper presented at the SSRC Conference on the Foreign Policy Consequences of Economic and Political Liberalization. Ballyvaughan, Ireland.
  • Garrett, G. (1995) ‘From the Luxembourg compromise to codecision: decision making in the European Union’, Electoral Studies 14(3): 289–308.
  • Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. (1996) ‘An institutional critique of intergovernmentalism’, International Organization 50(2): 269–99. doi: 10.1017/S0020818300028563
  • Greenberg, J. (1979) ‘Consistent majority rule over compact sets of alternatives’, Econometrica 47: 627–36. doi: 10.2307/1910410
  • Hagemann, S. (2008) ‘Voting, statements and coalition-building in the Council from 1999 to 2006’, in D. Naurin and H. Wallace (eds), Unveiling the Council of the European Union: Games Governments Play in Brussels, New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 36–63.
  • Hagemann, S. and De Clerk-Sachsse, J. (2007) ‘Old rules, new game. Decision-making in the Council of Ministers after the 2004 enlargement’, Special Report, Brussels: Centre for European Policy Studies.
  • Hayes-Renshaw, F. and Wallace, H. (1997) The Council of Ministers (1st edn), Basingstoke: Macmillan.
  • Hayes-Renshaw, F., van Aken, W. and Wallace, H. (2006) ‘When and why the EU Council of Ministers votes explicitly’, Journal of Common Market Studies 44(1): 161–94. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5965.2006.00618.x
  • Heisenberg, D. (2005) ‘The institution of ‘consensus’ in the European Union: formal versus informal decision-making in the Council’, European Journal of Political Research 44(1): 65–90. doi: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.2005.00219.x
  • Huber, J. and Shipan, C. (2002) Deliberate Discretion? Institutional Foundations of Bureaucratic Autonomy, Cambridge: Cambridge: University Press.
  • Hug, S. and König, T. (2002) ‘In view of ratification: governmental preferences and domestic constraints at the Amsterdam Intergovernmental Conference’, International Organization 56(2): 447–76. doi: 10.1162/002081802320005531
  • Kaplow, L. (1995) ‘A model of the optimal complexity of legal rules’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 11(1): 150–63.
  • König, T. and Junge, D. (2009) ‘Why don't veto players use their power?’, European Union Politics 10(4): 507–34. doi: 10.1177/1465116509346780
  • Kreilinger, V. (2012) ‘The making of a new treaty: six rounds of political bargaining’, Policy Brief No. 32, February, Notre Europe.
  • Koremenos, B. (2011) ‘An economic analysis of international rulemaking’, Paper presented at the American Society for International Law, Los Angeles.
  • Lange, P. (1993) ‘Maastricht and the social protocol: why did they do it?’, Politics and Society 21: 5–36. doi: 10.1177/0032329293021001002
  • Lewis, J. (1998a) ‘Is the ‘hard bargaining’ image of the Council misleading? The Committee of Permanent Representatives and the Local Elections Directive’, Journal of Common Market Studies 36 (4): 479–504. doi: 10.1111/1468-5965.00136
  • Lewis, J. (1998b) ‘The international problem-solving capacities of the Council: The Committee of Permanent Representatives and the methods of community’, Discussion Paper 1/98, Max-Planck-Institute für Gesellschaftsforschung.
  • Lewis, J. (2000) ‘The methods of community in EU decision-making and administrative rivalry in the Council's infrastructure’, Journal of European Public Policy 7(2): 261–89. doi: 10.1080/135017600343197
  • Marks, G., Hooghe, L. and Blank, K. (1996) ‘European integration from the 1980s: state-centric v. multi-level governance’, Journal of Common Market Studies 34(3): 341–78.
  • Martin, L. (1992) ‘Institutions and cooperation: sanctions during the Falkland Islands conflict’, International Security 16: 143–78. doi: 10.2307/2539190
  • Martin, L. (1993) ‘International and domestic institutions in the EMU process’, Economics & Politics 5: 125–44. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0343.1993.tb00071.x
  • Mattila, M. and Lane, J. (2001) ‘Why unanimity in the Council? A roll call analysis of Council voting’, European Union Politics 2(1): 31–52. doi: 10.1177/1465116501002001002
  • Mattila, M. (2004) ‘Contested decisions: Empirical analysis of voting in the European Union Council of Ministers’, European Journal of Political Research 43: 29–50.
  • Mattila, M. (2008) ‘Voting and coalitions in the Council after the enlargement’, In D. Naurin and H. Wallace (eds), Unveiling the Council of the European Union: Games Governments Play in Brussels, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Meunier, S. (2000) ‘What single voice? European institutions and EU–US trade negotiations’, International Organization 54(1): 103–35. doi: 10.1162/002081800551136
  • Moravcsik, A. (1991) ‘Negotiating the Single European Act: national interests and conventional statecraft in the European Community’, International Organization 45(1): 19–56. doi: 10.1017/S0020818300001387
  • Moravcsik, A. (1993) ‘Preferences and POWER in the European Community: a liberal intergovernmentalist approach’, Journal of Common Market Studies 31(4): 473–524. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5965.1993.tb00477.x
  • Ogus, A. (1992) ‘Information, error costs and regulation’, International Review of Law and Economics 12(4): 411–21. doi: 10.1016/0144-8188(92)90019-N
  • Peters, G. (1997) ‘Escaping the joint-decision trap: repetition and sectoral politics in the European Union’, West European Politics 20(2): 22–36. doi: 10.1080/01402389708425189
  • Poast, P. (2012) ‘Does issue linkage work? Evidence from European alliance negotiations, 1860 to 1945’, International Organization 66(2): 277–310.
  • Proksh, S. (2012) ‘Revealing constitutional preferences in the European convention’, in D. Finke, T. Konig, S. Proksch, and G. Tsebelis (eds), Reforming the European Union: Realizing the Impossible, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 62–75.
  • Riker, W. (1982) Liberalism against Populism, San Fransisco, CA: W.H. Freeman.
  • Scharpf, F. (1988) ‘The joint-decision trap: lessons from German federalism and European integration’, Public Administration 66(3): 239–78. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9299.1988.tb00694.x
  • Schneider, G., Finke, D. and Bailer, S. (2010) ‘Bargaining power in the European Union: an evaluation of competing game-theoretic models’, Political Studies 58: 85–103. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9248.2009.00774.x
  • Sebenius, J. (1983) ‘Negotiation arithmetic: adding and subtracting issues and parties’, International Organization 37(2): 281–316. doi: 10.1017/S002081830003438X
  • Steunenberg, B. (1994) ‘Decision making under different institutional arrangements: legislation by the European Community’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 150(4): 642–69.
  • Thomson, R. (2011) Resolving Controversy in the European Union, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Tollison, R.D. and Willett, T.D. (1979) ‘An economic theory of mutually advantageous issue linkages in international regimes’, International Organization 33(Autumn): 425–49. doi: 10.1017/S0020818300032252
  • Tsebelis, G. (1994) ‘The power of the European Parliament as a conditional agenda-setter’, American Political Science Review 88: 128–42. doi: 10.2307/2944886
  • Tsebelis, G. (2013) ‘Bridging qualified majority and unanimity decisionmaking in the EU’, Journal of European Public Policy 20(8): 1083–1103. doi: 10.1080/13501763.2013.788368
  • Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. (2001) ‘The institutional foundations of intergovernmentalism and supranationalism in the European Union’, International Organization 55(2): 357–90. doi: 10.1162/00208180151140603
  • Van Schendelen, M. (1996) ‘“The Council decides”: does the Council decide?’, Journal of Common Market Studies 34(4): 531–48. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5965.1996.tb00589.x
  • Voigt, S. (2009) ‘Explaining constitutional garrulity’, International Review of Law and Economics 29: 290–303. doi: 10.1016/j.irle.2009.06.002
  • Westlake, M. (1995) The Council of the European Union, London: Cartermill.
  • Weber, S. and Wiesmeth, H. (1991) ‘Issue linkage in the European Community’, Journal of Common Market Studies 29: 255–67. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5965.1991.tb00392.x

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.