214
Views
6
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

Polycentric versus hierarchical tertiary centres: comparing San Diego and Tijuana

Pages 361-377 | Received 19 Jan 2016, Accepted 30 May 2016, Published online: 29 Jun 2016

References

  • Aguilar, A. G., & Alvarado, C. (2005). La reestructuración del espacio urbano de la Ciudad de México ¿Hacia la metrópoli multinodal? In A. G. Aguilar (ed.), Procesos metropolitanos grandes ciudades. Dinámicas recientes en México y otros países (pp. 265–307). México: Miguel Angel Porrúa.
  • Alegría, T. (1994). Segregación socioespacial urbana. El ejemplo de Tijuana. Estudios demográficos y urbanos, 9(2), 411–428.
  • Alegría, T. (1992). Desarrollo urbano en la frontera México-Estados Unidos. México: Colección Regiones, CONACULTA.
  • Alegría, T. (1997). Centrality and location of employment in greater Lima. In PromPerú (ed.), Peru: Beyond the reforms. PromPerú summer internship program 1996 (pp. 199–225). Lima: Imagen y Medios.
  • Alegría, T. (2012). The transborder metropolis in question: The case of Tijuana and San Diego. In J. Kun & F. Montezemolo (eds), Tijuana dreaming: Life and art at the global border (pp. 148–174). Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
  • Alonso, W. (1964). Location and land use. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  • Anas, A., Arnott, R., & Small, K. (1998). Urban spatial structure. Journal of Economics Literature, 36(3), 1426–1464.
  • Anas, A., & Kim, I. (1996). General equilibrium models of polycentric urban land use with endogenous congestion and job agglomeration. Journal of Urban Economics, 40(2), 232–256. doi:10.1006/juec.1996.0031
  • Anderson, N., & Bogart, W. (2001). The structure of sprawl: Identifying and characterizing employment centers in polycentric metropolitan areas. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 60(1), 147–169. doi:10.1111/ajes.2001.60.issue-1
  • Berry, B., & Parr, J. (1988). Market centres and retail location. Englewood Cliff, NJ: Prentice Hall.
  • Bogart, W., & Ferry, W. (1999). Employment centres in greater Cleveland: Evidence of evolution in a formerly monocentric city. Urban Studies, 36(12), 2099–2110. doi:10.1080/0042098992566
  • Bourdieu, P. (1990). Sociología y Cultura. México: Grijalbo, CONACULTA.
  • Cermeño, R., Mayer, D., & Martínez, A. (2009). Convergencia, divergencia y estratificación. El Trimestre Económico, LXXVI(2)(302), 349–378.
  • Cervero, R., & Wu, K.-L. (1997). Polycentrism, commuting, and residential location in the San Francisco Bay area. Environment and Planning A, 29(5), 865–886. doi:10.1068/a290865
  • Eaton, C., & Lipsey, R. (1982). An economic theory of central places. The Economic Journal, 92(365), 56–72. doi:10.2307/2232256
  • Fernández-Maldonado, A. M., Romein, A., Verkoren, O., & Parente Paula Pessoa, R. (2014). Polycentric structures in Latin American metropolitan areas: Identifying employment sub-centres. Regional Studies, 48(12), 1954–1971. doi:10.1080/00343404.2013.786827
  • Forstall, R., & Greene, R. P. (1997). Defining job concentrations: The Los Angeles case. Urban Geography, 18(8), 705–739. doi:10.2747/0272-3638.18.8.705
  • Förster, M., & Pearson, M. (2002) Income distribution and poverty in the OECD area: Trend and driving forces. OECD Economic Studies, 2002(1), 7–39.
  • Fujita, M., & Ogawa, H. (1982). Multiple equilibria and structural transition of non-monocentric urban configurations. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 12(2), 161–196. doi:10.1016/0166-0462(82)90031-X
  • Gerber, J. (2014, June 5–6). Income in the border region 1993-2010. Presentation slide in Conference: NAFTA at 20: Effects on the North America market, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Houston, TX. Retrieved 7 May 2016, from http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/research/events/2014/14nafta_gerber.pdf
  • Giuliano, G., & Small, K. (1991). Subcenters in the Los Angeles region. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 21(2), 163–182. doi:10.1016/0166-0462(91)90032-I
  • Gordon, P., & Richardson, H. (1996). Beyond polycentricity: The dispersed metropolis, Los Angeles, 1970-1990. Journal of the American Planning Association, 62(3), 289–295. doi:10.1080/01944369608975695
  • Henderson, V., & Slade, E. (1993). Development games in non-monocentric cities. Journal of Urban Economics, 34(2), 207–229. doi:10.1006/juec.1993.1034
  • Herzog, L. A., & Sohn, C. (2014). The cross-border metropolis in a global age: A conceptual model and empirical evidence from the US–Mexico and European border regions. Global Society, 28(4), 441–461. doi:10.1080/13600826.2014.948539
  • McDonald, J. F. (1987). The identification of urban employment subcenters. Journal of Urban Economics, 21(2), 242–258. doi:10.1016/0094-1190(87)90017-9
  • McKinsey Global Institute. (2014). A tale of two Mexicos: Growth and prosperity in a two-speed economy. Mexico City: McKinsey. Retrieved 7 May 2016, from http://www.mckinsey.com/global-themes/americas/a-tale-of-two-mexicos
  • McMillen, D. (2001). Nonparametric employment subcenter identification. Journal of Urban Economics, 50(3), 448–473. doi:10.1006/juec.2001.2228
  • McMillen, D., & McDonald, J. F. (1998). Suburban subcenters and employment density in metropolitan Chicago. Journal of Urban Economics, 43(2), 157–180. doi:10.1006/juec.1997.2038
  • Parkin, M., Esquivel, G., & Ávalos, M. (2006). Microeconomía: Versión para Latinoamérica. México: Pearson Educación.
  • Richardson, H. W. (1988). Monocentric vs. policentric models: The future of urban economics in regional science. The Annals of Regional Science, 22(2), 1–12. doi:10.1007/BF01287319
  • Richardson, H. W. (1977). The new urban economics and alternatives. London: Pion Limited.
  • Rodriguez-Gamez, L., & Dallerba, S. (2012). Spatial distribution of employment in Hermosillo, 1999–2004. Urban Studies, 49(16), 3663–3678. doi:10.1177/0042098012448552
  • Ross, S., & Yinger, J. (1995). Comparative static analysis of open urban models with a full labor market and suburban employment. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 25(5), 575–605. doi:10.1016/0166-0462(95)02089-D
  • Schulz, N., & Stahl, K. (1996). Do consumers search for the highest price? Oligopoly equilibrium and monopoly optimum in differentiated-products markets. The RAND Journal of Economics, 27(3), 542–562. doi:10.2307/2555843
  • Seale, J. L., Regmi, A., & Bernstein, J. A. (2003). International evidence on food consumption patterns (Technical bulletin no. 1904). Washington, DC: Economic Research Service/USDA.
  • Stahl, K. (1987). Theories of urban business location. In E. Mills (ed.), Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 2, pp. 759–820). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
  • Sullivan, A. M. (1986). A general equilibrium model with agglomerative economies and decentralized employment. Journal of Urban Economics, 20(1), 55–74. doi:10.1016/0094-1190(86)90015-X
  • West, D., Von Hohenbalken, B., & Kroner, K. (1985). Tests of intraurban central place theories. The Economic Journal, 95(377), 101–117. doi:10.2307/2233471
  • White, M. (1999). Urban areas with decentralized employment: Theory and empirical work. In E. Mills & P. Cheshire (eds), Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1375–1412). New York, NY: North-Holland.
  • Wieand, K. (1987). An extension of the monocentric urban spatial equilibrium model to a multicenter setting: The case of the two-center city. Journal of Urban Economics, 21(3), 259–271. doi:10.1016/0094-1190(87)90001-5

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.