4,763
Views
43
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Standard articles

Local governments and their arm’s length bodies

, &

ABSTRACT

In this paper, we discuss the state of the art on the creation of arm’s length bodies (ALBs) by local governments. We make three main contributions. First, there are many different types of ALBs and each country has its own categories; an expert survey was held identifying three common types of body, to enable future comparative research. Second, we point out that the creation of ALBs has led to a number of new challenges for local governments, particularly regarding governing bodies at arm’s length to ensure ALBs’ good performance. A lack of capacity and information have to be countered, for example, by increased monitoring – also for democratic accountability purposes. Special attention is needed for the multiple principal problem that arises when local governments jointly create ALBs. Third, research into local ALBs is still in its early stages. We present a research agenda to develop knowledge on the topic.

Introduction

Due to the combined effects of decreasing public budgets, New Public Management reforms and large-scale decentralisations by national governments, local governments worldwide have nowadays organised the delivery of public services more and more at arm’s length (John Citation2001; Kuhlman and Bouckaert Citation2016).Footnote1 Local governments can organise this in different ways: they can outsource tasks, collaborate with private or societal partners, or hive off parts of their own organisation thereby creating so-called arm’s length bodies (ALBs). This contribution will focus on the latter form.

There are different types of ALBs, ranging from semi-autonomous organisations to private law-based corporations owned by local governments (Van Thiel Citation2004). Countries differ in the types of ALBs that are established, depending on, for example, legal context or state traditions. In some countries, the creation of ALBs goes back decades (Van Genugten Citation2008), while in other countries, the recent financial crisis has spurred local governments to externalise (Ferry et al. Citation2018; Kuhlman and Bouckaert Citation2016). An overview of what arm’s length service delivery at the local level nowadays looks like across countries is, however, lacking (Torsteinsen Citation2019).

Despite its widespread, the creation of ALBs at the local level is – in contrast to a similar trend at the national level (see, for example, Verhoest et al. Citation2012) – largely understudied (Cambini et al. Citation2011; Kuhlman and Bouckaert Citation2016; Lidström Citation2017; Torsteinsen Citation2019; Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2017). The literature that reports on the local level focuses predominantly on contracting out and privatisation (e.g., Brown and Potoski Citation2003; Dijkgraaf, Gradus, and Melenberg Citation2003; Domberger and Jensen Citation1997; Hefetz and Warner Citation2004; Hirsch Citation1995; Van Genugten Citation2008), and to a lesser extent and more recently on corporatisation (Citroni, Lippi, and Profeti Citation2013; Ferry et al. Citation2018; Florio and Fecher Citation2011; Grossi and Reichard Citation2008; Krause and Van Thiel Citation2018; Tavares Citation2017; Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2017). Consequently, the literature on local ALBs is not only limited, but also fragmented.

Furthermore, the literature mainly focuses on motives for and effects (mainly effectiveness and efficiency) of arm’s length service delivery, but does not touch upon the new governance and steering issues that have arisen as a result of the increased use of ALBs. Municipalities no longer have a solely hierarchical steering relationship with the organisations that are providing public services. Instead, they have an additional contracting relationship, in which they have to ensure the delivery of local public services. This poses several challenges for the governments involved (Krause and Van Thiel Citation2018; Papenfuß et al. Citation2018; Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2017, Citation2019b).

In this overview article, we will first discuss the types of ALBs that exist in several countries, based on an expert survey. In the second part, we delve into the literature to list the most important research findings so far. We focus in particular on the new governance dilemmas that the use of ALBs has created for local governments. Using principal-agent theory, we will describe these dilemmas and present some recent insights on the topic. Finally, we discuss which questions are or should be on the agenda for research into ALBs at the local level.

Arm’s length bodies at the local level

Arm’s length bodies at the local level can take many forms, depending on the local context and legal traditions. Unfortunately, researchers often group together and juxtapose ‘public’ and ‘private’ bodies without accurately specifying what type of bodies they investigate (Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2017). This lack of a clear and uniform terminology complicates research into ALBs, in particular, comparative research. To solve this problem, we present a categorisation of ALBs at the local level, based on Van Thiel’s typology (Van Thiel Citation2012) of agencies at the national level and Torsteinsen and Van Genugten’s application (Torsteinsen and Van Genugten Citation2016) thereof to the local level. These typologies consist of five types of agencies ranging from type 0 agencies – traditional in-house delivery – that are actually not at arm’s length of (local) government, to three types of agencies (type 1, 2 and 3) that can be understood as ALBs, and type 4 agencies in which governments only have a contracting relationship with a public or private body but no ownership relation as in the case of ALBs (see definitions below). Both type 0 and type 4 agencies are common at the local level in most European countries. Apart from England, where most areas of local public services have moved away from in-house delivery, type 0 can still be found in most countries at the local level. The same is true for type 4 agencies. In particular, in England and The Netherlands there has been a great amount of contracting out since the 1980s covering many services, while this process started a decade later in other countries, including Belgium, Norway and Spain, according to local experts whom we consulted (see below). The extent of contracting out varies from country to country and from one local government to another.

In the remainder of this paper, we focus on the three types of agencies that can be understood as ALBs (type 1, 2 and 3). ALBs can be defined as ‘organizations which spend public money and fulfil a public function but exist with some degree of independence from politicians’ (Greve, Flinders, and van Thiel Citation1999, 139). The degree of independence or autonomy varies per ALB and relates to conditions under which it operates, for example, its source of finances and belonging to the public domain (Allix and van Thiel Citation2005; Greve, Flinders, and van Thiel Citation1999). These conditions vary per country and sometimes even per municipality within a country. Therefore, our categorisation of ALBs is not exhaustive nor mutually exclusive and based on only two dimensions, namely structural and legal autonomy (Verhoest et al. Citation2004). Structural autonomy refers to ‘the extent to which the agency is shielded from influence through lines of hierarchy and accountability’ (Verhoest et al. Citation2004, 105), while legal autonomy refers to ‘the extent to which the legal status of the agency prevents the government from altering the allocation of decision-making competencies or makes such changes more difficult’ (Verhoest et al. Citation2004, 106). Regarding the dimension of legal autonomy, type 1 ALBs do not have a separate legal status, while type 2 and 3 ALBs do. The degree of structural autonomy increases from type 1 ALBs to type 3 ALBs, meaning that local authorities’ level of accountability to local councils and hierarchical control mechanisms available to local authorities decrease.

At the end of 2018, we sent out a survey to 26 (mainly European) academic experts in the field of public administration specialised in local government and asked them to categorise the local ALBs in their country according to our categorisation (see Appendix). We used an expert survey as this allowed us to collect information that cannot be gathered using a literature review because of a lack of uniform terminology or through document analysis due to language barriers. We received responses from 18 experts, of which seven experts reported not to be able to give us the requested information, due to upcoming or recent reforms (Finland, Romania), lack of data (Estonia), lack of time, and lack of knowledge on this specific subject; two experts could only provide us reports that were difficult to translate to our typology. In total, we collected information from 13 countries: Belgium (Flanders) (BE), Croatia (HR), Denmark (DK), England (EN), France (FR), Germany (DE), Hungary (HU), Italy (IT), Norway (NO), Portugal (PT), Spain (ES), Sweden (SE), and The Netherlands (NL). The data on Norway and Germany were collected in previous comparative projects on this subject (Papenfuß et al. Citation2018; Torsteinsen and Van Genugten Citation2016). presents the results.

Table 1. Typology of ALBs in 13 countries.

shows that the three types of ALBs exist in all these European countries. Moreover, ALBs are found in a broad range of sectors providing a broad range of services (from social welfare services to utility services). Since the 1990s/2000s, in particular, type 3 ALBs are increasing. This is, for example, the case in Belgium, Croatia, Denmark, Italy, Norway, Portugal, and The Netherlands. In Sweden, type 3 ALBs are even the majority of ALBs (93%). An exception is Hungary, where the number of type 3 ALBs has not changed significantly since the 1990s. In Portugal, following the increase of type 3 ALBs since 1998, there was a significant reduction in numbers after the financial bailout in 2011, which intriguingly contradicts the rise in numbers after the crisis in England (Ferry et al. Citation2018).

Taking a closer look at the three types of ALB, all countries have type 1 ALBs at the local level. These ALBs are units within the local government without a separate legal status, but with a degree of managerial autonomy concerning internal operational matters (personnel, organisation). For example in Portugal, these in-house delivery units have a separate fund in the municipal budget. In Norway and The Netherlands, contract-like agreements are set-up to formulate performance obligations. The degree of managerial discretion varies considerably, within and between countries. In some countries, this type of ALB is used for municipal tasks in general, while in other countries they are mainly used for one type of service, for example, for communal tasks in Croatia, social and cultural services in Italy, for utility services in Portugal, and for investments and urban planning in France. In most countries, type 1 ALBs are owned by a single municipality, but the joint committees in Sweden are created by two or more municipalities and the metropolitan agencies in France can also be created by more than one municipality and/or different level government authorities.

Type 2 ALBs are public law-based entities with a separate legal status, and can be found in all countries, but there is a great variety in forms within and between countries. One notable difference is the distinction in some countries between municipal and inter-municipal forms (for example, in Belgium, France, Hungary, and Italy), while type 2 ALBs in other countries are solely inter-municipal (for example, in Denmark, Norway, Portugal, and Sweden) and/or inter-governmental (for example, in Spain and The Netherlands) in nature. In some countries, such as Belgium, France and Spain, non-profit and private bodies can also participate in these inter-municipal/inter-governmental forms. A second form of variation is that within the inter-municipal forms a distinction is made between compulsory and voluntary inter-municipal cooperation in some countries (for example, Portugal and The Netherlands). A third form of type 2 ALBs that exist in some countries are non-profit, single-purpose institutions established on the basis of a specific law (Croatia, France, and Germany) or by statute or ministerial decision (England). In the latter case, not all bodies are based in a law, but effectively they operate as though they were.

Type 3 ALBs are private law-based organisations established by or on behalf of local government(s) and are found in all countries. Common forms of this type are the private law based limited liability company of which local governments have majority ownership (Croatia, Denmark, England, France, Germany, Hungary, Italy, Norway, Sweden, and The Netherlands) and the foundation (Croatia, Italy, Spain, Sweden, and The Netherlands). In Portugal, this type of ALB is based in a mix of public and private law. In all countries, type 3 ALBs can be single-owned or jointly owned by municipalities. In some countries, other government levels can be co-establisher as well (for example, in Croatia and The Netherlands). Mixed ownership of public and private owners also exists. For example, in Italy, mixed ownership is increasingly used, whereas in Sweden and The Netherlands this is quite modest. Besides the difference in legal form, the possibilities for accountability and control of ALBs are larger for type 2 ALBs than for type 3 ALBs, hence type 3 ALBs have more leeway to make their own decisions (cf. structural autonomy, Verhoest et al. Citation2004).

The expert survey confirms what we know from the literature so far: there is a large variety in forms of ALBs (Ferry et al. Citation2018; Torsteinsen Citation2019; Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2017). And then one should be aware that the literature is not even covering all countries and policy sectors equally. There is a dominance of economists in research on ALBs, a dominance of some European countries (The Netherlands, Spain, Italy, Portugal) and a dominance of some sectors (e.g., utilities such as water, public transport, waste collection). This implies that there is still much research to do on this topic, a point to which we will return in the final section.

Prominent themes in research on ALBs

To gain an overview of the state of the art, we analysed review studies on arm’s length service delivery at the local level (among others: Bel and Fageda Citation2007; Bel and Warner Citation2008, Citation2015; Grossi, Papenfuß, and Tremblay Citation2015; Tavares Citation2017; Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2017). We will focus on three prominent themes: the motives of local governments to establish ALBs; findings on the performance of ALBs; and the new governance dilemmas for local governments (next section).

Factors explaining the choice for service delivery via ALBs

Two types of causes are mentioned for the creation of local ALBs (Bel and Fageda Citation2007): economic and political causes.

Economic causes are fiscal stress and budget restrictions which induce governments to externalise (e.g., Andrews et al. Citation2019; Bel and Fageda Citation2010; Citroni, Lippi, and Profeti Citation2013; Gradus, Dijkgraaf, and Wassenaar Citation2014; Grossi and Reichard Citation2008). This is either instigated by the belief that market organisations and ALBs will perform more efficiently than government organisations, or by the belief that a particular task is not a core government responsibility anymore and therefore can be transferred to the market. Another economic motive is anticipated cost savings due to the introduction of competition or economies of scale (e.g., Bel and Fageda Citation2010). The latter in particular is an important motive for smaller municipalities establishing jointly owned type 2 and 3 ALBs (Bel and Fageda Citation2010; Citroni, Lippi, and Profeti Citation2013; Hulst and Van Montfort Citation2012; LeRoux and Carr Citation2007; Silvestre, Marques, and Gomes Citation2018; Allers and De Greef Citation2018) to cope with scarce local financial resources and cutbacks. Joint ALBs are expected to enhance the quality and range of service delivery. Another motive for joint ALBs are the scale and complexity of social processes and policy problems that require a capacity that goes beyond the scale and boundaries of a single municipality.

Political motives include the desire to win the support of interest groups (such as unions or industry) having a particular interest in a specific form of public service delivery (Bel and Fageda Citation2010). For example, many type 2 and 3 ALBs have a board in which members of interest groups can be (and are) appointed (see also below). Another political motive is ideology. Rule of left-wing political parties is found to be related to public delivery, while right-wing political parties can be linked to contracting out and privatisation (Bel and Fageda Citation2010; Gradus, Dijkgraaf and Wassenaar Citation2014; Tavares and Camões Citation2010). A third political motive for putting public service delivery at arm's length, in particular, type 2 and 3 ALBs, is political instability to avoid service disruptions or to shift blame to external providers (Bordeaux Citation2004; Rodrigues, Tavares, and De Araújo Citation2012; Tavares Citation2017; Tavares and Camões Citation2010). By putting public services at arm’s length, politicians may try to avoid blame when performance is poor – although in practice this is quite difficult as citizens often still anticipate the government to intervene (Van Slyke and Roch Citation2004).

Performance of ALBs

Performance of public service delivery bodies is frequently studied, often to contrast public and private bodies. However, the focus of most of these studies is more on contracting-out and privatisation than on ALBs. Initial studies showed success (Domberger and Jensen Citation1997; Hodge Citation2000), but over time, research started showing that privatisation and contracting-out did not increase efficiency as much as originally presumed (Bel and Warner Citation2008).

The limited success over time of contracting-out and privatisation, however, did not prevent municipalities from searching for new ways to incorporate market pressures in local public service delivery (Voorn, Van Thiel, and Van Genugten Citation2018). The consensus among academics and practitioners seemed to be not that markets had failed to bring efficiency, but that markets had failed to develop. Therefore, from the early 2000s onwards, local public service delivery focused around introducing novel forms of service delivery, often relying on the market- or business-like conditions in some way (Argento, Grossi, Tagesson, and Collin Citation2010; Voorn, Van Thiel, and Van Genugten Citation2018). Such forms included municipally owned corporations and mixed firms (type 2 and 3 ALBs). Particularly municipally owned corporations have become increasingly popular (Grossi and Reichard Citation2008; Tavares Citation2017; Tavares and Camoes Citation2007; Tavares and Camões Citation2010; Voorn, Van Thiel, and Van Genugten Citation2018). Whether their creation has led to a more effective and efficient public service delivery is however not evident. Like other ALBs, it is difficult to steer and monitor these corporations (see also below). Moreover, corporatisation does not necessarily take place for public service reasons, and could be used as a way for political representatives to shift blame for poor management to the directors of the new municipally owned corporation (Bordeaux Citation2004; Tavares and Camoes Citation2007). Next, autonomy could also be used to avoid budget rules, to make municipal budgets look healthier than they actually are, or to alleviate fiscal stress (Citroni, Lippi, and Profeti Citation2013; Grossi and Reichard Citation2008; Tavares Citation2017). Therefore, whether corporatisation is effective or not is one of the critical current questions in local public service delivery. A systematic review of the literature by Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel (Citation2017) tentatively suggests a positive effect, although it is highly contingent on the sector and municipal capacity (an issue we will return to in the next section).

Governance dilemmas for local governments

To model the governance relationship between local governments and ALBs, principal-agent theory is frequently used (Allers and Van Ommeren Citation2016; Bel and Warner Citation2008, Citation2015; Boyne Citation1998; Feiock Citation2007; Garrone, Grilli, and Rousseau Citation2013; Hefetz and Warner Citation2004; Reeves Citation2013; Sørensen Citation2007; Van Slyke Citation2006; Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2017, Citation2019b). In this economic model, the local government is the principal who hires an agent (ALB) to carry out a particular task. As the agent is more expert at the task, the principal faces uncertainty whether the agent will indeed perform as agreed, and not serve only its own interests. To compensate for his information disadvantage, the principal will have to invest in monitoring devices or offer incentives to the agent. Local governments that want to manage ALBs may run into a number of problems, that may be more severe when the structural autonomy is greater (i.e., when moving from type 1 to type 3 ALBs) We discuss the problems of (1) local government capacity, (2) goal divergence, accountability and control, (3) multiple principals, (4) corporate governance, and (5) hollowing out of local government.

Local government capacity

Compared to state or national governments, local governments have less capacity to manage at arm’s length. By virtue of their smaller size, they have less expertise in management (Brown and Potoski Citation2006; Buenrostro and Bocco Citation2003; Plummer Citation2013), less access to technical knowledge or service expertise (Buenrostro and Bocco Citation2003), and a lack of expertise in establishing salient contracts and in monitoring (Brown and Potoski Citation2003, Citation2006; Ernita Joaquin and Greitens Citation2012; Hefetz and Warner Citation2004). Local governments may also face a more general lack of resources (Dollery, Crase, and Byrnes Citation2006; Voorn et al. Citation2019a), a problem that is nowadays more severe due to post-crisis austerity (Bolgherini Citation2014; Lowndes and Gardner Citation2016; Overmans and Noordegraaf Citation2014; Peck Citation2014).

Local government capacity can differ per municipality and service (Brown and Potoski Citation2003, Citation2006; Hefetz and Warner Citation2011). That is, capacity problems seem greater in smaller, rural municipalities than in urban municipalities, and for services that are more technical or have less overt public objectives local governments require more capacity due to the difficulty of monitoring and evaluating service delivery. However, investing in capacity proves to be more difficult for smaller municipalities.

The problem may be smaller in type 1 ALBs, as this type of ALB is still part of the municipal hierarchical organisation. However, when creating a stand-alone organisation (i.e., type 2 and 3 ALBs), staff and expertise often moves to this new organisation. This leaves municipalities’ staff without the necessary expertise to manage these ALBs.

Goal divergence, accountability and control

Directors of ALBs may have objectives different from municipalities: they might want to divert funds for private gains or prestige (such as by asking for higher salaries or greater number of employees than necessary) or might disagree with municipalities about objectives (cf. Holmstrom and Tirole Citation1989). This creates goal divergence that can cause problems for municipalities.Footnote2

Goal divergence is a key reason why governance is required in the relationship between municipalities and ALBs. Such governance, however, is not without costs. Because of asymmetric information between municipalities and ALBs – ameliorated by lack of local government capacity – steering and monitoring protocols are required, especially in cases where multiple stakeholders are involved like in joint type 2 and 3 ALBs (Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2019b). Clear directives from the municipality build the ALB’s awareness of expectations, and gives the municipality a criterion to audit. Similarly, incentives such as variable pay can align the director’s interest with that of the municipality. Monitoring the director is also practical, presuming it is not too costly. However, there are still findings that as the distance between ALBs and municipalities increases (i.e., moving from type 1 ALBs to type 3 ALBs), the municipalities’ objectives are less likely to be satisfied (Brown and Potoski Citation2003) and accountability can be lost (Cäker and Nyland Citation2017; Moynihan Citation2006; Spicer Citation2017).

Multiple principals

Principal-agent problems intensify when multiple stakeholders (in joint type 2 and 3 ALBs) are involved in service delivery. Such joint service delivery, that can take place through for example inter-municipal bodies or institutional public–private partnerships (Bel and Sebo Citation2018; Blaeschke and Haug Citation2018; Cäker and Nyland Citation2017; Carini, Giacomini, and Teodori Citation2019; Soukopová and Vaceková Citation2018; Sørensen Citation2007; Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2017, Citation2019b) can potentially induce conflicts in governance and monitoring. For example, local governments can face free-riding problems or duplication in monitoring if there is no agreement on which principal will be in charge of monitoring, which can cause inefficiency. Moreover, individual municipalities may have incentives to pressure the ALB to put their own interests first, and such cross-pressure can potentially cause more inefficiency (Garrone, Grilli, and Rousseau Citation2013; Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2019b). In institutional public–private partnerships (Argento et al. Citation2010; Da Cruz and Marques Citation2012), for instance, both the public and private partner can try to pressure the ALB to reflect their interest first and foremost, and spend a lot of resources in the process of doing so. Much less emphasised, however, is that the same can occur for inter-municipal service delivery when municipalities are heterogeneous in interests. One proposed solution for this is to coordinate between local governments, for example, by delegating governance to a single party elected by the municipal principals, but further research as to whether or not this is effective is required (Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2019b).

Corporate governance

Type 2 and 3 ALBs often have a corporate structure with a one or two-tier board. The one-tier model is the predominant model in Anglo–Saxon countries, while the two-tier board with an executive and non-executive board is a common model in continental European countries (Van Thiel Citation2015). In the latter model, the executive board manages the ALB and the non-executive board officially is advisor and supervisor of the ALB. The corporate structure makes the corporate governance of these ALBs a relevant topic. Corporate governance is understood as the mechanisms for control, monitoring and management of legally and/or economically independent entities owned by local governments (Cadbury Citation2000; Shleifer and Vishny Citation1997). This is often associated with guidelines regarding the behaviour and structure of the executive and non-executive board and, in particular, the accountability of these boards (e.g., Aguilera and Cuervo-Cazurra Citation2009; Zattoni and Cuomo Citation2008).

Serious challenges and problems can be discerned in the corporate governance of ALBs (Bruton et al. Citation2015; Grossi, Papenfuß, and Tremblay Citation2015). An important element of corporate governance is the composition and behaviour of the executive board (Hinna, De Nito, and Mangia Citation2010; Meyer, Höllerer, and Leixnering Citation2018; Van der Walt and Ingley Citation2003). Besides in empirical studies, this is stressed in codes for good corporate governance (Papenfuß et al. Citation2018). Executive boards are expected to have a positive effect on ALBs’ performance (Cornforth Citation2012; Hinna, De Nito, and Mangia Citation2010). In case of joint ALBs, the strategic decision-making of the executive board can, however, be complicated by varying interests among the multiple stakeholders (Bruton et al. Citation2015). Furthermore, as municipal owners often have the power of appointing board members, they may appoint likeminded executive directors (with a previous career in the public sector or a political background) (Bruton et al. Citation2015; Flinders and Matthews Citation2010). This type of government control, called politicisation (Flinders and Matthews Citation2010; Peters and Pierre Citation2004), might lead to a politically desired focus on maintenance of employment and other social concerns, but might negatively affect the economic performance of the ALB (Bruton et al. Citation2015). Moreover, municipal owners might use reward-based political patronage as a means of favouritism used to reward political minions (Meyer, Höllerer, and Leixnering Citation2018).

Hollowing out of local government

Putting public service delivery at arm's length from the local government might ‘hollow out’ local government. Hollowing out refers to (local) governments’ loss of functions and loss of autonomy due to reforms such as privatisation, putting services at arm's length, and processes of centralisation and Europeanisation (Jacobsen Citation2009). In the context of ALBs, the loss of power of political institutions, such as democratically responsible local councils, to non-elected bodies can create a democratic deficit. For example, in type 2 and 3 ALBs, power is shifted to appointed boards (Flinders and Matthews Citation2010) which limits the ‘responsibility, accountability and authority for public action’ of municipal councils (Skelcher Citation2010, 8). In ALBs that are jointly owned by municipalities, the possibilities for steering and control of individual municipal councils is limited (Sørensen Citation2007; Voorn, Van Genugten, and Van Thiel Citation2019b). Another cause for the democratic deficit is that ALBs are often single-purpose bodies (Jacobsen Citation2009), which limits the possibilities of integral decision-making to deal with wicked issues. At the same time, layman councillors who often lack specialised knowledge struggle with controlling these specialised ALBs (Jacobsen Citation2009). For example, they do not always have enough interest, time or capacity to interpret the information arising from performance monitoring (Askim Citation2007; Ter Bogt Citation2004; Voorn et al. Citation2019a). As a result, control and monitoring of ALBs are often limited to the minimum legal requirements (Aars and Ringkjøb Citation2011).

Research agenda

The foregoing discussion of the state of the art of research and research findings on the use of ALBs by local governments has shown that there are still many questions unanswered. In this final section, we will present three research priorities. There are many more topics that could be studied, but we believe that these are the most urgent questions, both for academics and practitioners.

First, the definition and types of ALBs need more clarification. Public service delivery encompasses both the production, provision and purchase of services. Further refinement is needed, but can only be done when we have a better overview of the different types and numbers of ALBs in various countries. Our expert survey confirmed that local governments in Europe are all making extensive use of all three types of ALBs. It has however proven difficult to obtain more exact numbers of such bodies and their size in terms of, for example, budget or sectors. More research is therefore first and foremost needed to make an inventory of types of ALBs, their size and the sectors in which they operate. The current literature is fragmented and limited, and biased towards certain sectors, in particular water and waste. The typology that was used for the survey can be instrumental for comparative research, even if it has its limitations. We do not expect that it is possible to get full clarity on all the different types, given all the differences in legal contexts and state traditions, but the three categories/types appear to be relatively easy to recognise for the experts.

A second priority for future research concerns the effects of the creation of ALBs, not only in terms of economic effects but also in terms of democratic effects. Little is known, for example, what citizens know and think of the fact that most of public service delivery nowadays is carried out by non-core government bodies (see for an exception James et al. Citation2016). Moreover, we have identified a number of ways in which a democratic deficit has arisen as a result of the creation of ALBs, particularly in case of type 2 and 3 ALBs. Most ALBs are non-elected and therefore not held accountable directly. Local governments can monitor the ALB and report this to local councils and citizens, but they are hindered by the limitations in their steering and information processing capacities. And in the case of jointly owned ALBs the possibilities for individual local governments to intervene or monitor are even more limited. Research should delve more into these issues, also to develop useful solutions for local governments.

Third and final, the new governance issues need to be studied more. Governments are facing the dilemma on how to deal with bodies operating at arm’s length. We have identified a number of problems that all deserve attention. However, two issues stand out most: the multiple principal problems and the role of boards. Both occur most in type 2 and 3 ALBs. Small municipalities try to solve their lack of steering capacity by joining forces with neighbouring municipalities (also expecting economies of scale). However, a multiple principal situation creates new problems, both on the side of the principals (e.g., who is going to be in charge of monitoring) and of the agent (e.g., being subjected to cross pressure from different principals). Principal-agent theory’s solution is to coordinate among the principals, but that is difficult to achieve among different governments. Researchers should not only study these problems, but also consider different solutions like alternative theories and models, such as stewardship theory (see note 2). Research into boards has so far focused mostly on the composition of the boards (e.g., diversity) or its remuneration (see, e.g., Papenfuß et al. Citation2018). Knowledge of the internal workings and the effectiveness of boards are, therefore, one of the unchartered territories for researchers to go and explore.

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank the following academic experts for filling out their expert survey: Germà Bel (University of Barcelona, Spain), Jérôme Dupuis (University of Lille, France), Giuseppe Grossi (Kristianstad University, Sweden, and Nord University Norway), Gyorgy Hajnal (Corvinus University of Budapest, Hungary), Christian Lindholst (Aalborg University, Denmark), Anamarija Musa (University of Zagreb, Croatia), Chris Skelcher (University of Birmingham, England), António Tavares (University of Minho, Portugal), Koen Verhoest (University of Antwerp, Belgium).

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Additional information

Notes on contributors

Marieke Van Genugten

Dr. Marieke van Genugten is assistant professor at the Department of Public Administration, Radboud University, Nijmegen.

Sandra Van Thiel

Prof.dr. Sandra van Thiel is Professor of Public Management at the Department of Public Administration, Radboud University, Nijmegen.

Bart Voorn

Bart Voorn Msc is a PhD candidate at the Department of Public Administration, Radboud University, Nijmegen.

Notes

1. Public service delivery can encompass production, purchase and/or provision of public services.

2. Goal divergence may not always be true for public sector organisations (Van Thiel Citation2016). A more applicable model for the relationship between governments and ALBs, in that case, may be stewardship theory (Davis, Schoorman, and Donaldson Citation1997).

References

  • Aars, J., and H.-E. Ringkjøb. 2011. “Local Democracy Td: The Political Control of Local Government Enterprises in Norway.” Public Management Review 13 (6): 825–844. doi:10.1080/14719037.2010.539110.
  • Aguilera, R. V., and A. Cuervo-Cazurra. 2009. “Codes of Good Governance.” Corporate Governance 17 (1): 376–387. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8683.2009.00737.x.
  • Allers, M. A., and B. Van Ommeren. 2016. “Intermunicipal Cooperation, Municipal Amalgamation and the Price of Credit.” Local Government Studies 42 (5): 717–738. doi:10.1080/03003930.2016.1171754.
  • Allers, M. A., and J. A. De Greef. 2018. “Intermunicipal Cooperation, Public Spending and Service Levels.” Local Government Studies 44 (1): 127–150. doi:10.1080/03003930.2017.1380630.
  • Allix, M., and S. van Thiel. 2005. “Mapping the Field of Quasi-autonomous Organizations in France and Italy.” International Journal of Public Management 8 (1): 39–55.
  • Andrews, R., L. Ferry, C. Skelcher, and P. Wegorowski. 2019. “Corporatization in the Public Sector: Explaining the Growth of Local Government Companies.” Public Administration Review. Advance online publication. doi:10.1111/puar.13052.
  • Argento, D., G. Grossi, T. Tagesson, and S.-O. Collin. 2010. “The 'Externalisation' of Local Public Service Delivery: Experience in Italy and Sweden.” International Journal of Public Policy 5 (1): 41–56. doi: 10.1504/IJPP.2010.029780.
  • Askim, J. 2007. “How Do Politicians Use Performance Information? an Analysis of the Norwegian Local Government Experience.” International Review of Administrative Sciences 73 (3): 453–472. doi:10.1177/0020852307081152.
  • Bel, G., and M. Sebo 2018. “Does Inter-Municipal Cooperation Really Reduce Delivery Costs? an Empirical Evaluation of the Role of Scale Economies, Transaction Costs, and Governance Arrangements.” Working paper No. 201816. Barcelona: University of Barcelona, Research Institute of Applied Economics.
  • Bel, G., and M. Warner. 2008. “Does Privatization of Solid Waste and Water Services Reduce Costs? A Review of Empirical Studies.” Resources, Conservation and Recycling 52 (12): 1337–1348. doi:10.1016/j.resconrec.2008.07.014.
  • Bel, G., and M. E. Warner. 2015. “Inter‐Municipal Cooperation and Costs: Expectations and Evidence.” Public Administration 93 (1): 52–67. doi:10.1111/padm.2015.93.issue-1.
  • Bel, G., and X. Fageda. 2007. “Why Do Local Governments Privatize Public Services? A Survey of Empirical Studies.” Local Government Studies 33 (4): 517–534. doi:10.1080/03003930701417528.
  • Bel, G., and X. Fageda. 2010. “Partial Privatisation in Local Services Delivery: an Empirical Analysis Of The Choice Of Mixed Firms.” Local Government Studies 36 (1): 129-149. doi:10.1080/03003930903435856.
  • Blaeschke, F., and P. Haug. 2018. “Does Intermunicipal Cooperation Increase Efficiency? A Conditional Metafrontier Approach for the Hessian Wastewater Sector.” Local Government Studies 44 (1): 151–171. doi:10.1080/03003930.2017.1395741.
  • Bolgherini, S. 2014. “Can Austerity Lead to Recentralisation? Italian Local Government during the Economic Crisis.” South European Society and Politics 19 (2): 193–214. doi:10.1080/13608746.2014.895086.
  • Bordeaux, C. 2004. “A Question of Genesis: An Analysis of the Determinants of Public Authorities.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 15 (3): 441–462. doi:10.1093/jopart/mui020.
  • Boyne, G. A. 1998. “Competitive Tendering in Local Government: A Review of Theory and Evidence.” Public Administration 76 (4): 695–712. doi:10.1111/padm.1998.76.issue-4.
  • Brown, T., and M. Potoski. 2006. “Contracting for Management: Assessing Management Capacity under Alternative Service Delivery Arrangements.” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 25 (2): 323–346. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1520-6688.
  • Brown, T. L., and M. Potoski. 2003. “Contract-Management Capacity in Municipal and County Governments.” Public Administration Review 63 (2): 153–164. doi:10.1111/puar.2003.63.issue-2.
  • Bruton, G., M. Peng, D. Ahlstrom, C. Stand, and K. Xu. 2015. “State-Owned Enterprises around the World as Hybrid Organizations.” Academy of Management Perspectives 29 (1): 92–114. doi:10.5465/amp.2013.0069.
  • Buenrostro, O., and G. Bocco. 2003. “Solid Waste Management in Municipalities in Mexico: Goals and Perspectives.” Resources, Conservation and Recycling 39 (3): 251–263. doi:10.1016/S0921-3449(03)00031-4.
  • Cadbury, A. 2000. “The Corporate Governance Agenda.” Corporate Governance 8 (1): 7–15. doi:10.1111/1467-8683.00175.
  • Cäker, M., and K. Nyland. 2017. “Inter‐Organizational Cooperation Challenging Hierarchical Accountability: The Dominated Actors in a Municipal Joint Venture.” Financial Accountability and Management 33 (1): 102–120. doi:10.1111/faam.12115.
  • Cambini, C., M. Filippini, M. Piacenza, and D. Vannoni. 2011. “Corporatization and Firm Performance: Evidence from Publicly-Provided Local Utilities.” Review of Law and Economics 7 (1): 191–213. doi:10.2202/1555-5879.1428.
  • Carini, C., D. Giacomini, and C. Teodori. 2019. “Accounting Reform in Italy and Perceptions on the Local Government Consolidated Report.” International Journal of Public Administration 42 (3): 195–204. doi:10.1080/01900692.2017.1423500.
  • Citroni, G., A. Lippi, and S. Profeti. 2013. “Remapping the State: Inter-Municipal Cooperation through Corporatisation and Public-Private Governance Structures.” Local Government Studies 39 (2): 208–234. doi:10.1080/03003930.2012.707615.
  • Cornforth, C. 2012. “Nonprofit Governance Research: Limitations of the Focus on Boards and Suggestions for New Directions.” Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 41 (6): 1116-1135. doi:10.1177/0899764011427959.
  • Da Cruz, N. F., and R. C. Marques. 2012. “Mixed Companies and Local Governance: No Man Can Serve Two Masters.” Public Administration 90 (3): 737–758. doi:10.1111/padm.2012.90.issue-3.
  • Davis, J. H., F. D. Schoorman, and L. Donaldson. 1997. “Toward a Stewardship Theory of Management.” The Academy of Management Review 22 (1): 20–47. doi:10.5465/amr.1997.9707180258.
  • Dijkgraaf, E., R. H. Gradus, and B. Melenberg. 2003. “Contracting Out Refuse Collection.” Empirical Economics 28 (3): 553–570. doi:10.1007/s001810200145.
  • Dollery, B., L. Crase, and J. Byrnes. 2006. “Local Government Failure: Why Does Australian Local Government Experience Permanent Financial Austerity?” Australian Journal of Political Science 41 (3): 339–353. doi:10.1080/10361140600848952.
  • Domberger, S., and P. Jensen. 1997. “Contracting Out by the Public Sector: Theory, Evidence, Prospects.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 13 (4): 67–78. doi:10.1093/oxrep/13.4.67.
  • Ernita Joaquin, M., and T. J. Greitens. 2012. “Contract Management Capacity Breakdown? an Analysis of US Local Governments.” Public Administration Review 72 (6): 807–816. doi:10.1111/puar.2012.72.issue-6.
  • Feiock, R. C. 2007. “Rational Choice and Regional Governance.” Journal of Urban Affairs 29: 47–63. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9906.2007.00322.x.
  • Ferry, L., R. Andrews, C. Skelcher, and P. Wegorowski. 2018. “New Development: Corporatization of Local Authorities in England in the Wake of Austerity 2010–2016.” Public Money and Management 38 (6): 477–480. doi:10.1080/09540962.2018.1486629.
  • Flinders, M., and F. Matthews. 2010. “Think Again: Patronage, Governance and the Smarter State.” Policy and Politics 38 (4): 639–656.
  • Florio, M., and F. Fecher. 2011. “The Future of Public Enterprises: Contributions to a New Disclosure.” Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 82 (4): 361–373. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8292.2011.00445.x.
  • Garrone, P., L. Grilli, and X. Rousseau. 2013. “Management Discretion and Political Interference in Municipal Enterprises. Evidence from Italian Utilities.” Local Government Studies 39 (4): 514–540. doi:10.1080/03003930.2012.726198.
  • Gradus, R. H., E. Dijkgraaf, and M. Wassenaar. 2014. “Understanding Mixed Forms Of Refuse Collection, Privatization, and its Reverse in The Netherlands.” International Public Management Journal 17 (3): 328-343. doi:10.1080/10967494.2014.935237.
  • Greve, C., M. V. Flinders, and S. van Thiel. 1999. “Quangos: What’s in a Name? Defining Quasi-autonomous Bodies from a Comparative Perspective.” Governance 12 (1): 129–146. doi:10.1111/0952-1895.951999095.
  • Grossi, G., and C. Reichard. 2008. “Municipal Corporatization in Germany and Italy.” Public Management Review 10 (5): 597–617. doi:10.1080/14719030802264275.
  • Grossi, G., U. Papenfuß, and M. Tremblay. 2015. “Corporate Governance and Accountability of State-Owned Enterprises: Relevance for Science and Society and Interdisciplinary Research Perspectives.” International Journal of Public Sector Management 28 (4): 274–285. doi:10.1108/IJPSM-09-2015-0166.
  • Hefetz, A., and M. E. Warner. 2004. “Privatization and Its Reverse: Explaining the Dynamics of the Government Contracting Process.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 14 (2): 171–190. doi:10.1093/jopart/muh012.
  • Hefetz, A., and M. E. Warner. 2011. “Contracting or Public Delivery? the Importance of Service, Market, and Management Characteristics.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 22 (2): 289–317. doi:10.1093/jopart/mur006.
  • Hinna, A., E. De Nito, and G. Mangia. 2010. “Board of Directors within Public Organisations: A Literature Review.” International Journal of Business Governance and Ethics 5 (3): 131–156. doi:10.1504/IJBGE.2010.033343.
  • Hirsch, W. 1995. “Contracting Out by Urban Governments: A Review.” Urban Affairs Quarterly 30 (3): 458–472. doi:10.1177/107808749503000307.
  • Hodge, G. A. 2000. Privatization: An International Review of Performance. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press.
  • Holmstrom, B. R., and J. Tirole. 1989. “The Theory of the Firm.” In Handbook of Industrial Organization 1, edited by R. Schmalensee and R. Willig, 61–133. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
  • Hulst, R., and A. Van Montfort. 2012. “Institutional Features of Inter-Municipal Cooperation: Cooperative Arrangements and Their National Contexts.” Public Policy and Administration 27 (2): 121–144. doi:10.1177/0952076711403026.
  • Jacobsen, D. I. 2009. “A Tragedy of the Councils? Exploring the Hollowing-Out Hypothesis: The Case of Norwegian Local Authorities.” Lex Localis 7 (3): 221–242. doi:10.4335/84.
  • James, O., S. Jilke, C. Petersen, and S. Van de Walle. 2016. “Citizens’ Blame of Politicians for Public Service Failure: Experimental Evidence about Blame Reduction through Delegation and Contracting.” Public Administration Review 76 (1): 83–93. doi:10.1111/puar.12471.
  • John, P. 2001. Local Governance in Western Europe. London: Sage.
  • Krause, T., and S. Van Thiel. 2018. “Perceived Managerial Autonomy in Municipally Owned Corporations: Disentangling The Impact Of Output Control, Process Control, and Policy-profession Conflict.” Public Management Review 21 (2): 187–211. doi: 10.1080/14719037.2018.1473472.
  • Kuhlman, S., and G. Bouckaert. 2016. Local Public Sector Reforms in Times of Crisis: National Trajectories and International Comparisons. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
  • LeRoux, K., and J. B. Carr. 2007. “Explaining Local Government Cooperation on Public Works: Evidence from Michigan.” Public Works Management and Policy 12 (1): 344–358. doi:10.1177/1087724X07302586.
  • Lidström, A. 2017. “Public Authorities and Intermunicipal Cooperation in a European Context.” Urban Affairs Review 53 (2): 403–409. doi:10.1177/1078087416630613.
  • Lowndes, V., and A. Gardner. 2016. “Local Governance under the Conservatives: Super-Austerity, Devolution and the ‘smarter State’.” Local Government Studies 42 (3): 357–375. doi:10.1080/03003930.2016.1150837.
  • Meyer, R., M. Höllerer, and S. Leixnering. 2018. “A Question of Value(s): Political Connectedness and Executive Compensation in Public Sector Organizations.” International Public Management Journal 21 (3): 477–500. doi:10.1080/10967494.2015.1094162.
  • Moynihan, D. P. 2006. “Ambiguity in Policy Lessons: The Agencification Experience.” Public Administration 84 (4): 1029–1050. doi:10.1111/padm.2006.84.issue-4.
  • Overmans, J. F. A., and M. Noordegraaf. 2014. “Managing Austerity: Rhetorical and Real Responses to Fiscal Stress in Local Government.” Public Money and Management 34 (2): 99–106. doi:10.1080/09540962.2014.887517.
  • Papenfuß, U., M. Van Genugten, J. De Kruijf, and S. Van Thiel. 2018. “Implementation of EU Initiatives on Gender Diversity and Executive Directors’ Pay in Municipally-Owned Enterprises in Germany and the Netherlands.” Public Money and Management 38 (2): 87–96. doi:10.1080/09540962.2018.1407133.
  • Peck, J. 2014. “Pushing Austerity: State Failure, Municipal Bankruptcy and the Crises of Fiscal Federalism in the USA.” Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 7 (1): 17–44. doi:10.1093/cjres/rst018.
  • Peters, B., and J. Pierre. 2004. Politicization of the Civil Service in Comparative Perspective. London: Routledge.
  • Plummer, J. 2013. Municipalities and Community Participation: A Sourcebook for Capacity Building. London: Routledge.
  • Reeves, E. 2013. “The Not so Good, the Bad and the Ugly: Over Twelve Years of PPP in Ireland.” Local Government Studies 39 (3): 375–395. doi:10.1080/03003930.2013.781023.
  • Rodrigues, M., A. F. Tavares, and J. F. F. E. De Araújo. 2012. “Municipal Service Delivery: The Role of Transaction Costs in the Choice between Alternative Governance Mechanisms.” Local Government Studies 38 (5): 615–638. doi:10.1080/03003930.2012.666211.
  • Shleifer, A., and R. W. Vishny. 1997. “A Survey of Corporate Governance.” Journal of Finance 52 (2): 737–783. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb04820.x.
  • Silvestre, H. C., R. C. Marques, and R. C. Gomes. 2018. “Joined-up Government of Utilities: A Meta-Review on A Public-Private Partnership and Inter-Municipal Cooperation in the Water and Wastewater Industries.” Public Management Review 20 (4): 607–631. doi:10.1080/14719037.2017.1363906.
  • Skelcher, C. 2010. “Changing Images of the State: Overloaded, Hollow-out, Congested.” Public Policy and Administration 15 (3): 3–19. doi:10.1177/095207670001500302.
  • Sørensen, R. J. 2007. “Does Dispersed Public Ownership Impair Efficiency? the Case of Refuse Collection in Norway.” Public Administration 85: 1045–1058. doi:10.1111/padm.2007.85.issue-4.
  • Soukopová, J., and G. Vaceková. 2018. “Internal Factors of Intermunicipal Cooperation: What Matters Most and Why?” Local Government Studies 44 (1): 105–126. doi:10.1080/03003930.2017.1395739.
  • Spicer, Z. 2017. “Bridging the Accountability and Transparency Gap in Inter-municipal Collaboration.” Local Government Studies 43 (3): 388–407. doi:10.1080/03003930.2017.1288617.
  • Tavares, A. F. 2017. “Ten Years After: Revisiting the Determinants of the Adoption of Municipal Corporations for Local Service Delivery.” Local Government Studies 43 (5): 697–706. doi:10.1080/03003930.2017.1356723.
  • Tavares, A. F., and P. J. Camöes. 2007. “Local Service Delivery Choices in Portugal: a Political Transaction Costs Framework.” Local Government Studies 33 (4): 535-553. doi:10.1080/03003930701417544.
  • Tavares, A. F., and P. J. Camões. 2010. “New Forms of Local Governance: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of Municipal Corporations in Portugal.” Public Management Review 12 (5): 587–606. doi:10.1080/14719031003633193.
  • Ter Bogt, H. J. 2004. “Politicians in Search of Performance Information? Survey Research on Dutch Aldermen’s Use of Performance Information.” Financial Accountability and Management 20 (3): 221–252. doi:10.1111/fam.2004.20.issue-3.
  • Torsteinsen, H., and M. Van Genugten. 2016. “Waste Management in the Netherlands and Norway – From In-House Delivery to Inter-Municipal Cooperation.” In Local Public Sector Reforms in Times of Crisis: National Trajectories and International Comparisons, edited by S. Kuhlman and G. Bouckaert, 205–220. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
  • Torsteinsen, H. 2019. “Debate: Corporatization in Local Government - the Need for a Comparative and Multi-Disciplinary Research Approach.” Public Money and Management 39 (1): 5–8. doi:10.1080/09540962.2019.1537702.
  • Van der Walt, N., and C. Ingley. 2003. “Board Dynamics and the Influence of Professional Background, Gender and Ethnic Diversity Of Directors.” Corporate Governance 11 (3): 218-234.
  • Van Genugten, M. 2008. The Art of Alignment: Transaction Cost Economics and Public Service Delivery at the Local Level. Enschede: University of Twente.
  • Van Slyke, D. M. 2006. “Agents or Stewards: Using Theory to Understand the Government-Nonprofit Social Service Contracting Relationship.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 17 (2): 157–187. doi:10.1093/jopart/mul012.
  • Van Slyke, D. M., and C. H. Roch. 2004. “What Do They Know, and Whom Do They Hold Accountable? Citizens in the Government-Nonprofit Contracting Relationship.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 14 (2): 191–209. doi:10.1093/jopart/muh013.
  • Van Thiel, S. 2004. “Quangos in Dutch Government.” In Unbundled Government: A Critical Analysis of the Government: A Critical Analysis of the Global Trend to Agencies, Quasi-autonomous Bodies and Contractualisation, edited by C. Pollitt and C. Talbot, 167–183. United Kingdom: Taylor and Francis.
  • Van Thiel, S. 2012. “Comparing Agencies across Countries.” In Government Agencies: Practices and Lessons from 30 Countries, edited by K. Verhoest, S. Van Thiel, G. Bouckaert, and P. Lægreid, 18–26. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Van Thiel, S. 2015. “Boards of Public Sector Organizations: A Typology with Dutch Illustrations.” International Journal of Public Sector Management 28 (4/5): 322–334. doi:10.1108/IJPSM-04-2015-0072.
  • Van Thiel, S. 2016. “Principal-agent Theory.” In Perspectives on Public Sector Reform, edited by S. Van de Walle and S. Groeneveld, 44–60. Abingdon: Routledge.
  • Verhoest, K., B. G. Peters, G. Bouckaert, and B. Verschuere. 2004. “The Study of Organizational Autonomy: A Conceptual Review.” Public Administration and Development 24 (2): 101–118. doi:10.1002/pad.316.
  • Verhoest, K., S. Van Thiel, G. Bouckaert, and P. Lægreid, Eds. 2012. Government Agencies: Practices and Lessons from 30 Countries. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Voorn, B., M. Van Genugten, and S. Van Thiel. 2017. “The Efficiency and Effectiveness of Municipally Owned Corporations: A Systematic Review.” Local Government Studies 43 (5): 820–841. doi:10.1080/03003930.2017.1319360.
  • Voorn, B., M. Van Genugten, and S. Van Thiel. 2019b. “Multiple Principals, Multiple Problems: A Framework for Effective Governance and A Research Agenda for Joint Service Delivery.” Public Administration 97: 671–685. doi:10.1111/padm.12587.
  • Voorn, B., S. Van Thiel, and M. Van Genugten. 2018. “Corporatization as More than a Recent Crisis-Driven Development.” Public Money and Management 38 (7): 481–482. doi:10.1080/09540962.2018.1527533.
  • Voorn, B., W. Nolden, M. Van Genugten, and S. Van Thiel 2019a. “Capacity, Expertise, Ideology, or Relations: Antecedents of Performance Management after Local Corporatization.” Paper presented at UiT Workshop on Corporatization in Local Government, Tromsø, Norway.
  • Zattoni, A., and F. Cuomo. 2008. “Why Adopt Codes of Good Governance? A Comparison of Institutional and Efficiency Perspectives.” Corporate Governance 16 (1): 1–15. doi:10.1111/corg.2008.16.issue-1.

Appendix.

Expert survey on ALBs

Dear country expert,

We are working on a paper about the steering relationship between local governments and arm’s length bodies. To set the scene we would like to write a section on arm’s length bodies at the local level in different countries. We have information on The Netherlands, Germany and Norway, but we don’t know much about these bodies in other countries. Therefore, we are asking for your support by providing us information on arm’s length bodies at the local level in your country. Attached you will find a document with a table. This table is based on Sandra van Thiel’s typology of arm’s length bodies at the national level (see attachment). We used this typology previously to compare arm’s length bodies (ALBs) in the Netherlands with ALBs in Germany and Norway. This worked quite well. The question to you is whether you would be so kind to fill out the table for ALBs at the local level in your country.

Please note when filling out the table, that we are interested in:

  • Whether all forms of the typology do indeed exist in your country at the local level

  • if so, what they are called

  • if so, whether you could give an indication of how common the different forms are (and if available give some figures)

  • if some forms do not exist – please leave the cell open

  • if some forms do not fit this typology – please indicate this below the table and explain how you would classify these forms

  • Major trends of development (e.g., increase in some forms)

  • Particularities of ALOs at the local level in your country (e.g., with regard to legal form, legal provisions, (corporate) governance)

  • Other thoughts on the typology or subject in general – please indicate this below the table

We look forward to a positive response from you. Thank you in advance for your support.

Name of expert: .......................................................................

Country: .......................................................................................