883
Views
30
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
PAPERS

With or Without Clusters: Facilitating Innovation through a Differentiated and Combined Network Approach

&
Pages 1169-1188 | Received 01 Feb 2007, Accepted 01 Apr 2007, Published online: 11 Nov 2008
 

Abstract

Over the past decades, economic and innovation policy across Europe moved in the direction of creating regional clusters of related firms and institutions. Creating clusters through public policy is risky, complex and costly, however. Moreover, it is not necessary to rely on clusters to stimulate innovation. A differentiated and combined network approach to enhancing innovation and stimulating economic growth may be more efficient and effective, especially though not exclusively in regions lacking clusters. The challenge of such a policy is to mitigate the bottlenecks associated with “global pipeline”, “local buzz” and “stand alone” strategies used by innovative firms and to combine these strategies with a view to their complementarity in terms of knowledge effects. Private and semi-public brokers will be key in the evolving policy, as timely organizational change is crucial for continued innovation, while brokers also need to mitigate governance problems. This requires region-specific knowledge in terms of sectors, life cycles, institutional and socio-cultural factors, and yields spatially differentiated and differentiating adjustment strategies. The role of public policy is to assist in recruiting, provide start-up funding and monitor brokers. With this, policy moves towards a decentralized, process-based, region-specific, spatially diverging and multi-level system of innovation that is geared towards the evolving innovation strategies of firms.

Notes

Please note that we separate the cluster from the network concept, defining clusters as “geographical concentrations of firms involved in the same of similar activities, which may, but need not specialize, subcontract and co-operate with one another”, and networks as “a set of strategic, purposeful, preferential, sometimes repetitive and usually co-operative interactions between actors, which may, but need not operate in close vicinity” (Visser & Boschma, Citation2004, p. 801). There are different explanations for clustering in the sense of a long-term and endogenous process of geographical concentration (see Appendix 1). Clusters—in the sense of geographical concentrations, are out there, or they are not, which is radically different from the position of some “cluster enthusiasts” who put “the promotional cart before the analytic horse”, believing that “the detailed structure and workings of a cluster will become obvious soon enough once we begin to think about an activity in cluster terms” (Martin & Sunley, Citation2003).

Another source of opportunity costs is the lack of balance, within and across regions, of an all too strict focus on clusters. Not only does this increase the dependence of regions on the performance of cluster(s), implying enhanced vulnerability of the regional economy towards external shocks in specific markets (oral communication with Ulrich Witt, 1 December 2006; for a recent example see Van Dooren, Citation2006; for a more extensive discussion of this problem, see Frenken et al., Citation2007), but it also contributes to growing inequality within and between regions and in terms of innovation, economic growth and prosperity, which are a threat to stability in certain societies, as we have seen in developing nations (Todaro, Citation2000; Visser, Citation1996) and currently in the Russian Federation and China.

The Utrecht, Gooi & Eemland region has got a few specializations, but this does not mean that cluster processes (in the sense of Brenner, Citation2004) are on their way. The four identified clusters in Media, Business Services, IT Consultancy and Chemical subsectors are embryonic in at least two ways: (a) low concentration and specialization ratios, oscillating between 1.25 and 3 (which is low compared with Italian clusters; see Capello & Faggian, Citation2005); and (b) weak statistical relations with several innovation indicators (Atzema & Visser, Citation2005b, pp. 40–51).

The choice between, to combine or to exclude local, global or stand-alone strategies is likely to be path- and context-dependent, including differences across sectors, the phase of an industry or technology in the life cycle, institutional settings and socio-cultural factors.

These investments entail: a) informing other actors about one's “mental model” (North, Citation1994) and knowledge routines; b) explaining how and why one has arrived at this model; c) understanding alternative models and explanations.

Log in via your institution

Log in to Taylor & Francis Online

PDF download + Online access

  • 48 hours access to article PDF & online version
  • Article PDF can be downloaded
  • Article PDF can be printed
USD 53.00 Add to cart

Issue Purchase

  • 30 days online access to complete issue
  • Article PDFs can be downloaded
  • Article PDFs can be printed
USD 622.00 Add to cart

* Local tax will be added as applicable

Related Research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.