1,717
Views
2
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Overlap in external technology search locations and the breadth of IPR assets: lessons from the Security Software Industry

ABSTRACT

This study examines the effect of intellectual property rights (IPR) on firms’ geographic overlap strategy of external technology search (ETS) compared to rivals. I reveal that firms are able to realise less intensity of geographic overlap in ETS locations compared to competitors and that this outcome is a function of the breadth of their upstream (generality of patents) and downstream (diversification of trademarks) IPR tools. Accordingly, I conclude that both covariates influence the spatial isolation of ETS vis-à-vis competitors. The effect of generality of patents on isolation, however, is more pronounced in comparison with diversification of trademarks at strategic technology alliances, meanwhile the reverse scenario is true at acquisitions. I also reveal relevant findings about resource-rich organisations defined as those with the broadest portfolio of such up- and downstream IPR assets within the industry.

1. Introduction

Past literature on open innovation highlights the imperative role of knowledge and technology seeking for firms (Kim and Kogut Citation1996; Rosenkopf and Nerkar Citation2001). Such organisational behaviour that aims to source externally generated knowledge is more pronounced if the focal industry undergoes a rapid technological change (Chung and Alcácer Citation2002), and if technology development exhibits a clear pattern for complexity due to technological interdependencies (Dodgson Citation1989). Prior research indicates a strong correspondence between external technology search (ETS) and geography owing to the significant variation in innovative activity that can take place across regions within the same country (Almeida and Kogut Citation1999; Saxenian Citation1994), and to the specific factors that can be tapped at distinct locations (Cantwell Citation1989). Such crucial external factors can even be accessed from resource-poor firms if they are located in resource-rich areas that promote investment in technology innovation (Forman, Goldfarb, and Greenstein Citation2008).

At the same time, however, there exists another argument that can trigger a geographically isolated realisation of ETS from rival entities. As knowledge spillovers can be captured from geographically proximate competitors (Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Henderson Citation1993), a defensive argument concentrates on firms’ interest in protecting their own technological knowledge from rivals by a means of locating apart and avoiding geographic clustering (Shaver and Flyer Citation2000). As a matter of fact, studies recognise that firms can perceive the balance of knowledge in- and outflows (Cassiman and Veugelers Citation2002), and corresponding to possible knowledge spillover benefits, they can actively shape location strategies to preserve or augment their technical capabilities vis-à-vis rivals in the industry (Alcácer and Chung Citation2007).

Drawn from prior literature, firms can correspondingly notice the importance of ETS for their competitiveness, the manner by which relevant technology is spatially dispersed, and the limited number of locations where technology is presumably accessible. Furthermore, firms can discern the relevance of self-defence against non-deliberate knowledge outflows during their explorative undertakings. The central topic of this article is to merge geography and active location strategies, which has remained scant until now in the received openness literature. Thus, the first question is: Can we observe the strategic value of location choices in ETS and any corresponding patterns in varying intensity of geographic overlap? This raises the second question: What drives the intensity of geographic overlap in open innovation activities between firms?

In this paper, I explore these issues through distinguishing firms’ relative resources in intellectual property rights (IPR) at upstream and downstream levels. Consequently, I resort to patents and trademarks as both are quintessential technological and marketing resources, respectively (Zhou et al. Citation2016), that can enhance the competitive advantage of the firm due to being nonsubstitutable and costly to imitate (Barney Citation1991; Castanias and Helfat Citation1991). Further still, such assets can advantageously influence firms’ ability to adapt and to exploit new opportunities (Tripsas Citation1997; King and Tucci Citation2002). This standpoint is based on the breadth of these protected assets, captured by the generality of patents and the diversification of trademarks, which influences the firm’s competitive position in ETS associated with open innovation compared to its within-industry rivals.

In this context, I formulate the following three research hypotheses: 1. (2.) Firms with more general (diversified) stock of patents (trademarks) are more likely to have less intensity of geographic overlap in external technology search locations compared to rivals; 3. Resource-rich firms that achieve parity and score high either on the generality of patent or on the diversification of trademark, are more likely to have high intensity of geographic overlap in ETS locations with each other, conditioned by multiple contacts in the market niches of the focal industry.

I empirically test these propositions on a unique dataset that is built upon the worldwide Security Software Industry (SSI). The practise of external technology search in SSI is a widespread activity because (i) it is a technology-based industry with enhanced product innovation, (ii) competition is fierce implied by low entry barriers and a high hazard rate of firm exit, (iii) new lucrative product categories proliferate, and (iv) the design of a security software system is a complex undertaking (Giarratana Citation2004; Giarratana and Fosfuri Citation2007; Fosfuri, Giarratana, and Sebrek Citation2018).

Two distinct mechanisms of ETS are examined: acquisitions and strategic technology alliances that correspond to acquiring and sourcing – two crucial inbound processes defined by Dahlander and Gann (Citation2010). To this end, I assembled a comprehensive dataset of three years between 2000 and 2002. As the hypothesised relationships are inherently dyadic, I built up the sample of dyadic pairs of firms for which I incorporated 57 (51) security software firms in the sample on strategic technology alliances (acquisitions) that performed at least two ETS in the study period. I use the quadratic assignment procedure that permits me to analyse the sampled firms’ geographic dispersion of ETS in a dyadic fashion. To study the hypothesised links with more precision, following Alcácer (Citation2006) I apply three units of geographical classification: clusters, countries and economic regions.

My empirical results suggest that both IPR-based core covariates – patent generality and trademark diversification – support a lower extent of geographic overlap in external technology search compared to rivals. However, they play different roles depending on the type of the search activity, as trademarks support such an isolation process more than patents at acquisitions, while for patents the reverse case holds regarding strategic technology alliances. Other interesting findings are linked to resource-rich firms whose operationalisation was done separately both for patents and trademarks. The results imply that a high intensity of spatial overlap vis-à-vis similar research-rich competitors is achieved, only if both firms exhibit multimarket contact in the niches of the industry in question. The results associated with strategic technology alliances reveal that the significance of this effect depends on the level of geographic gradation applied.

This work links together several branches in the literature, such as openness of external technology search and the geographic component of firm strategy. I was able to demonstrate the strategic value of location choices where firms’ breadth of upstream and downstream intellectual property rights play an indispensable role. An important contribution of the study is that it jointly incorporates technology alliances and acquisitions as key external knowledge and technology channels for organisations. By constructing a detailed dataset on partners’ location of SSI incumbents, I assess that the intensity of geographic overlap in external technology search compared to rivals is a direct consequence of resource differentials in the breadth of firms’ IPR-related assets. In addition, the study can enhance our understanding of firms’ location patterns of ETS by applying a diverse geographical classification. Furthermore, I follow prior research that considers trademarks as important assets for firm strategy (e.g. Block et al. Citation2015; Fosfuri, Giarratana, and Luzzi Citation2008; Fosfuri and Giarratana Citation2009; Mendonça, Santos Pereira, and Godinho Citation2004). This paper offers a value addition in terms of measurement as it directly captures the diversification dimension of this downstream IPR asset. Finally, this paper joins with the line of academic enquiries (Block et al. Citation2014; De Vries et al. Citation2017; Helmers and Rogers Citation2010; Zhou et al. Citation2016) that mutually considers patents and trademarks in studying openness.

2. Theoretical background

The ability to compete in high-technology industries depends on the acquisition of competitive knowledge, implying, that a firm has to attain experience with the underlying science and related technological fields (Kim and Kogut Citation1996). Some of these newly acquired capabilities help the firm to respond rapidly to market changes and allow for expansion during windows of opportunity (Kim and Kogut Citation1996). Studying patenting activity in optical disc technology, Rosenkopf and Nerkar (Citation2001) show that exploration spanning organisational boundaries consistently generates higher impact on subsequent technological evolution, thereby it can provide for the explorer organisation a competitive advantage within the industry and an option to diversify. Resorting to external exploration is desirable as technological evolution is generated by communities of organisations (Rosenkopf and Tushman Citation1998). For instance, the evolution of products with the underlying components can be viewed as the result of variation, selection and retention processes that take place by a broad community of organisational actors (Rosenkopf and Nerkar Citation1999). This feature influences a firm’s technological trajectory and makes all industrial actors mutually interdependent.

To maintain or enhance competitive edge, firms might be motivated to employ ETS for search of new capabilities, and presumably to recombine those newly acquired or accessed capabilities with existing skills. This motive has been termed technology or knowledge seeking, and such organisational search behaviour can be more prevalent if a firm competes in a technology-intensive industry (Chung and Alcácer Citation2002). One can expect some firms to value locations’ traits that reflect the level of localised technical activity. The uniqueness of a location relies much on location-specific factors that can nurture technologies not available elsewhere (Cantwell Citation1989). Even a relatively resource-poor firm but one that is situated in a resource abundant location can considerably improve chances to realise investment in innovative processes (Forman, Goldfarb, and Greenstein Citation2008). Tapping localised technology sources is greatly enhanced by frequent inter-partner interaction as relevant knowledge can be tacit and the prerequisite of its transfer depends on physical propinquity (Kogut and Zander Citation1992). This idea that firms seeking new knowledge have to approach the target locations is reaffirmed by Almeida and Kogut (Citation1999). They demonstrate that localised knowledge builds upon cumulative ideas within regional boundaries, and as knowledge is frequently tacit that knowledge resides with engineers of a particular geographic community. For instance, science parks attract large enterprises that through spatial proximity enable them to satisfy their knowledge needs and to facilitate the transfer of tacit knowledge (le Duc and Lindeque Citation2018). Cantwell and Janne (Citation1999) bring evidence that firms emanating from leading technical centres are also likely to pursue technological strategies in which they geographically differentiate their innovative activities abroad. In contrast to firms from more laggard technical centres whose primary interest relies on catch-up, they are primarily focused on sourcing more diverse technical knowledge. Studying inward FDI into the United States, Chung and Alcácer (Citation2002) make a parallel inference, arguing that knowledge seeking takes place not only among technical laggards, but is also ubiquitous among technically leading firms.

Acknowledging the potential for higher added value and nonredundant knowledge to be captured from geographically distant organisations, a defensive argument puts emphasis on geographically isolating external technology search vis-à-vis competitors. Certain industries are based upon technical competition, which may force all participants to seek spillovers from competitors. The study by Shaver and Flyer (Citation2000) argues that firms with the best technologies have strong motivation to geographically distance themselves, otherwise their technologies with other key resources spill over to competitors which become stronger and eventually endanger the competitive position of the former. Chung and Alcácer (Citation2002) arrive to a similar conclusion in connection with foreign technologically leading flagship firms as they opt to spatially isolate themselves from existing clusters in the United States to prevent outward knowledge spillovers to rivals. Such unwanted outgoing knowledge spillover can occur as the level of knowledge in- and outflows is not exogenous to the firm, but the recipient firm can affect the extent of incoming spillovers through a deliberate innovation strategy (Cassiman and Veugelers Citation2002). In a related paper, Alcácer and Chung (Citation2007) recognise that firms are active entities in making decisions upon location strategies in terms of net spillover benefits they may obtain, and thus are aware of the possible cost of outward spillovers. Using information on European inventions and data about firms and location, Giarratana and Mariani (Citation2014) show that firms conducting research projects in locations with high levels of absorptive capability in a specific technology risk internal knowledge spillovers.

2.1. IPR assets and geographic overlap in ETS

The management literature on openness emphasises the strategic value of ETS locations choices that serve as key assumptions to the theory laid down. First, firms assign the importance of ETS in high-tech environments. Second, knowledge and technology are not concentrated but geographically dispersed, and there is a limited number of best locations for certain advanced types of knowledge and technology. Last, firms might apply self-defence from unintended knowledge spillover by diverging ETS from rivals. Therefore, ceteris paribus, there must be strong competition for the most attractive locations, implying that some firms should be able to exert an expelling effect or to first break-in into such locations; put differently, these firms should be able to reach a lower extent of geographic overlap through an isolation process in ETS locations vis-à-vis rivals. This represents a research gap in the open innovation management literature that I attempt to fill.

In turn, what moves the above process? This paper posits that an organisational strategy to flock with or to enjoy a position of spreading ETS geographically more extensively than within-industry competitors relates closely to firm resources. Namely, upstream and downstream organisational resources in intellectual property rights can potentially act as driving forces for firms to geographically isolate their external technology search networks. To this point, I examine patents and trademarks, the two types of IPR tools that, respectively, represent technological and marketing resources (Zhou et al. Citation2016). Both protected assets constitute as rare, not easily substitutable, costly and difficult to imitate internal organisational resources that may be key to the firm’s acquisition and maintenance of sustainable, competitive advantage (Barney Citation1991; Castanias and Helfat Citation1991). Preexisting assets with these qualities can positively affect firms’ ability to adapt and to exploit new opportunities (Tripsas Citation1997; King and Tucci Citation2002). In deriving the hypotheses, I utilise to the breadth of the endowments in patents and trademarks instead of the pure stock of such protected assets, proposing that resource differentials between firms affect the degree of geographic overlap in their ETS channels. A broader portfolio of protected assets can better support openness in search activities, taking into consideration a potentially significant geographic variation in innovative activity (Almeida and Kogut Citation1999), reuse of existing capabilities to generate inventions (Strumsky and Lobo Citation2015), constraints on firm resources (Garriga, Von Krogh, and Spaeth Citation2013), evaluation difficulties of partners’ resources and prospects (Reuer and Lahiri Citation2013), costs of identifying external knowledge inputs (Salge et al. Citation2013), and overall hidden costs (Cassiman and Valentini Citation2016).

Overall, firms with larger breadth of upstream and downstream IPR assets are expected to achieve less intensity of geographic overlap in ETS locations against their rivals because they can keep competitors out of strategically valuable locations (e.g. by breaking-in first or expelling rivals) or because they attempt to isolate themselves to diminish unintended knowledge spillovers and defend their competitive advantage.

3. Hypotheses

3.1. Upstream resources: generality of patents

A more general, industry-core patent portfolio (i.e. a stock of patented inventions with widespread impact) provides greater resilience and latitude in ETS which lowers the extent of geographic overlap vis-à-vis competitors for several reasons.

The first reason is strategic. Patents normally symbolise firms’ technological capabilities (Giarratana and Torrisi Citation2010), assist with building a positive technological image (Blind et al. Citation2006; Veer and Jell Citation2012), and help open innovation activities (Zobel, Balsmeier, and Chesbrough Citation2016). A firm with a portfolio of more general stock of industry-specific patents is more effective at applying competitive pressures to rivals in forming ETS links. Particularly, exhibiting variety in the generality dimension, patents look more attractive for generating knowledge flows in the eyes of potential partners, thus the focal firms can easily approach those firms that are located in capability rich areas. By a related consideration, owning a more general patent portfolio of widespread impact can signal a technology leader position in the industry (Garud and Kumaraswamy Citation1993) which might offer a possibility for exploiting this reputation of a technology champion, enabling the leader to create a spatially divergent set of technology search locations with respect to less capable rivals. Therefore, less-capable competitors will prove to be less attractive candidates which reduces their opportunities to break into a geographically divergent set of locations. An additional source of advantage is that a more general industry-core patent portfolio might render potential partners a necessary knowledge overlap, facilitating broader partner selection with complementary patents and technologies. This can be an important aspect for geographically distant R&D collaborations that entail difficulties to evaluate others’ resources and prospects (Reuer and Lahiri Citation2013).

The second reason is defensive and also indicates a lower extent of geographic overlap in technology search networks. Establishing multiple technological cooperations involves risk for the firm to infringe upon patents held by other entities. However, a more general patent portfolio of the searcher organisation through stronger bargaining power increases the likelihood of avoiding litigation or establishing friendly agreements with potential litigators. Through studying the semiconductor sector, Hall and Ziedonis (Citation2001) and Ziedonis (Citation2004) demonstrate that when there is a fragmented market for technologies, patent portfolios help resolve hold-up problems via the use of cross-licensing agreements. Consequently, a more general patent portfolio can shield the firm against IPR-related litigations and therefore may potentially dismantle legal barriers of geographically spreading ETS more extensively than the network of rivals with less general portfolios.

Third, firms with a more general patent portfolio obtain a different kind of benefit whereby, compared with and against competitors, they enjoy a geographic divergence of their technological search channels. A more general knowledge base creates a higher potential absorptive capacity (Lane and Lubatkin Citation1998; Zahra and George Citation2002) that extends an organisation’s possibility to value and assimilate external knowledge. This component increases the overall level of absorptive capacity that allows firms to manage external knowledge flows more efficiently, and, consequently, stimulate innovative outcomes (Escribano, Fosfuri, and Tribo Citation2009). This leads to less information asymmetry when evaluating the quality of the skills of potential partners or acquisition targets that operate in a different segment of the industry. Lower expected costs due to higher absorptive capacity give the firm more freedom for trial and error experimentation. Therefore, a firm incurs less search costs of ETS which permits spatial divergence augmentation of its open innovation locations compared to rivals.

Finally, a more general patent portfolio provides more universal skills that can increase knowledge coordination in ETS links. Improved knowledge coordination contributes to the better exploitation of synergies and to the rate of organisational learning (Zollo and Winter Citation2002). Furthermore, a more general knowledge base with enhanced learning potential can promote a ‘connect and develop’ strategy that leverages external capabilities in order to enrich the connecting firm’s innovation portfolio (Sakkab Citation2002), and can permit the reuse of existing capabilities to generate inventions (Strumsky and Lobo Citation2015).

As a result, by taking into account all the positive consequences of a more general patent portfolio for ETS associated with open innovation, I hypothesise the following:

Hypothesis 1. Firms with a more general preexisting stock of patents will have less intensity of geographic overlap in external technology search locations compared to rivals.

3.2. Downstream resources: diversification of trademarks

The next proposition suggests that firms with more diversified complementary or downstream assets to product commercialisation have strong incentives to spread external technology search in the geographic space and build up beneficial positions against rivals. Teece (Citation1986) argues that, in almost all cases, the successful commercialisation of an innovation requires complementary assets and that the ownership of such assets can position the innovator advantageously. Correspondingly, the lack of those assets can force a technology entrepreneur to sell its technology instead of commercialisation (Gans and Stern Citation2003; Arora and Ceccagnoli Citation2006). For instance, brand advertising can contribute to the creation of stronger downstream assets either by greater brand loyalty due to higher perceived customer differentiation (Lancaster Citation1984) or by elevating entry barriers to competitors when the brand acts as a reference in its category (Kapferer Citation1997).

An efficient form of creating downstream assets is through registering trademarks that secure legal marketing protection (Fosfuri, Giarratana, and Luzzi Citation2008) and technological investments by boosting the rate of appropriability (Block et al. Citation2015; Flikkema, De Man, and Castaldi Citation2014; Mendonça, Santos Pereira, and Godinho Citation2004). Differentiation is largely enhanced by trademarks that permit customers to distinguish a firm and its offerings from those of the competitors (Mendonça, Santos Pereira, and Godinho Citation2004; Fosfuri and Giarratana Citation2009) which reduces simultaneously their search costs (Cohen Citation1991). Trademarks key to the scope of operation is a signal of conscious investments into a firm’s own brands, reputation for perceived quality, customer loyalty and distribution channels (Mendonça, Santos Pereira, and Godinho Citation2004; Block et al. Citation2015). Investment into trademarks provides good protection of marketing efforts as a strong brand along with reputation for quality transforms into an intangible asset that is not easily imitable by competitors. Linking this with the fact that an efficacious way to own markets is to own brands (Aaker Citation1991), trademark registration represents valuable efforts to develop and strengthen a business. Relatedly, Gao and Hitt (Citation2012) have found that trademarks represent a signal of new product development capacity. Trademarks also protect brands against low-priced copycats as the aggrieved party can seek legal remedies for any market advantage enjoyed by the copycat due to confusion, mistake or deception (Warlop, Ratneshwar, and van Osselaer Citation2005). In consequence of the vantage-point for a successful commercialisation that emanates from several marketing- and reputation-related advantages, firms with a more diversified portfolio of trademarks seem more attractive to target organisations and can enjoy more freedom in selecting open innovation partners, as opposed to weaker rivals whose ETS activities would be expelled or limited. A diversified trademark portfolio might signal ample relevant marketing information about the firm, which is crucial in cases of geographically distant R&D collaboration and difficulty when determining would-be peers’ resources and prospects (Reuer and Lahiri Citation2013).

Past research points out correspondence between a firm’s own trademarks and its pecuniary features. For instance, Fosfuri and Giarratana (Citation2009) find that filed trademarks relevant to the industry in question imply larger financial firm value. Prior studies also detect that trademarks strongly correlate with company sales (Seethamraju Citation2003), stock market value (Smith and Parr Citation2000), firm value (Sandner and Block Citation2011), cash flow, Tobin’s q and return on assets (Krasnikov, Mishra, and Orozco Citation2009). As a consequence, one can expect a more diversified stock of trademarks concentrated in the focal industry to contribute more to the financial soundness of the firm compared to rivals that possess a less diversified portfolio. This implies that the focal firm has more resources for non-local search and can also become more attractive for potential partners due to larger investment freedom. In effect, more available resources to allocate can increase the geographic divergence of technology search channels compared with competitors that have a scarcity of such downstream assets.

Furthermore, a more diversified trademark holding generally encompasses brands from a broad range of product categories. To achieve wide product scope, the organisation had to undergo a continuous and repeated sequence of changes that identify the underlying organisational routines of this group of firms (Sorenson et al. Citation2006). Such firms might have presumably developed the ability to accommodate new technologies due to former expansions and the acumen to analyse the potential use of a technology due to the experience with a wide range of products (Fosfuri, Giarratana, and Sebrek Citation2018). Additionally, a diversified brand portfolio can prove to be beneficial from cost-efficiency considerations. For example, Cohen and Klepper (Citation1996) find that the returns on R&D are closely dependent on the range of a firm’s output because fixed costs related to R&D activities can be better spread and thus absorbed with more business applications. These organisational traits on firms with a diverse set of brands may involve a spatially divergent external search compared to their rivals.

Based on the above, the consequences of a more diversified trademark portfolio for ETS associated with open innovation leads to the next hypothesis:

Hypothesis 2. Firms with a more diversified preexisting stock of trademarks will have less intensity of geographic overlap in external technology search locations compared to rivals.

3.3. Resource richness, its parity and multimarket contacts

To this point, the arguments of Hypotheses 1 and 2 suggest that differences in the degree of breadth of upstream and downstream IPR assets influence the outcomes of competitive contests between pairs of firms at external technology search. As a consequence, large resources differentials prevent weaker rivals to occupy similar geographic locations in ETS. Nevertheless, these inquires do not permit drawing precise conclusions on ETS location strategies, if both firms of a given pair score high either on the generality of patent or on the diversification of trademark. Studying the ETS location behaviour of such intra-industry resource-rich firms is of prime interest in contrast to medium value firm pairs, for instance, which according to theory established in the prior two hypotheses are only able to apply less extensive ETS due to the limitations of their IPR resources.

Therefore, questions regarding equally resource-rich firms remain unanswered: If both members of a firm pair reach parity in the breadth of key IPR assets, then both rivals may equally break into valuable locations. Therefore, a more spatially similar ETS network would develop. I propose that such a process is moderated by the existence of a high extent of market overlap between the firms that they develop within their focal industry. Indeed, Sirmon, Grove and Hitt (Citation2008) found that the degree of parity in the resources held by the two rivals moderates the relationship between resource management and outcomes of competitive contests.

The precondition of multipoint competition is an organisational strategy in which the firm broadens its product portfolio and diversifies within its own industry (Giarratana and Fosfuri Citation2007; Li and Greenwood Citation2004). Firms having stakes in many product categories can enjoy different kinds of positional advantages like increased stability in a more uncertain business environment (Dobrev, Kim, and Carroll Citation2002), more strategic latitude for managers to hedge their bets (Sorenson Citation2000), increased entry barriers against newcomers (Lancaster Citation1990), beneficial positions at technology acquisitions (Fosfuri, Giarratana, and Sebrek Citation2018), higher survival chances (Dowell Citation2006; Giarratana and Fosfuri Citation2007) and better overall performance (Barroso and Giatarrana Citation2013; Zahavi and Lavie Citation2013). Furthermore, consumers might find it convenient to buy on the idea of one-stop shopping (Siggelkow Citation2003), and should consumer preference be positively correlated, a product bundling strategy might be implemented (Gandal, Markovich, and Riordan Citation2005).

In the model, I propose that if both members of a firm dyad are resource-rich in the breadth of their upstream or downstream IPR assets, and there is a high overlap of within-industry market niches, then it augments the convergence of their open innovation locations. I highlight three reasons that help explain such a competitive outcome. First, firms develop common interests for the same types of new technologies and knowledge as they operate in similar market segments serving the same groups of customers. This results in targeting a geographically similar network of external technology search which is more conspicuous if specific skills or technology can only be accessed in a limited number of locations.

The second reason is strategic and relates to the possibility of mutual forbearance. Multiplicity of contacts makes competitors recognise their interdependence, and hence advances the possibility of collusion (Karnani and Wernerfelt Citation1985). This leads to a more conscious coordination, development of information about each other and to a reduced intensity of market competition (Boeker et al. Citation1997). Mutual forbearance between two firms with high level of multimarket contacts is a stable strategy as it is buttressed with a lower rate of exit from the competitor’s market (Baum and Korn Citation1999). Furthermore, if the mutual forbearance agreement breaks, namely if overly aggressive rivalry is not undermined, then multimarket contacts widen the scope for punishing attempts of technology expropriation, knowledge dissipation or reverse engineering. Such retaliation can be realised in those market niches where the aggressor has more to lose than the responder (Bernheim and Whinston Citation1990), or the cost of defense is likely to be relatively low (Karnani and Wernerfelt Citation1985). One effective way to counter-attack is if the threatened firm starts to sell products applying predatory pricing in core, cash-cow niches of the aggressor where it can achieve the starkest possible retaliation on the attacking firm. Therefore, multimarket contacts with rivals facilitate a higher extent of ETS overlap due to less fear of negative spillover balance. Instead of a lengthy litigation process, it can directly provide the opportunity for retaliation on cash-cow niches of the deviating rival. In addition, similarly to our notion of resource parity, Li and Greenwood (Citation2004) found that similarity between firms facilitates rivals to capture more pecuniary benefits of multimarket contacts through mutual forbearance.

Third, the resource-partitioning model of organisational ecology demonstrates that the width of product portfolio through distinct forms of group identity development process shapes differently the adherence to quality, production methods, and clinging to customers and communities (Negro, Visentin, and Swaminathan Citation2014; Carroll and Swaminathan Citation2000; Swaminathan Citation2001). Consequently, to alleviate competitive threat posed by specialist firms, resource-rich, wide market-scoped generalists’ ETS might be affected by their competitive interdependence and collective identity that would eventually permit a more mutually supportive behaviour in ETS for this class of organisations. These arguments lead to the last hypotheses:

Hypothesis 3a(b). If both members of a firm-pair are resource-rich in their generality of patents (diversification of trademarks), and exhibit multiple contacts in their market niches, then they will have more intensity of geographic overlap in ETS locations with each other.

4. Data and methodology

4.1. Sample construction

To test these ideas, I resort to the Security Software Industry (SSI) which has its technological origins in the 1970s due to large investments made by the US government in military projects related to security of data transmissions. As a result, a sound scientific background in cryptography and encryption emerged through the involvement of large ICT firms and university departments which manifested in a historical, USPTO-registered patent stock. This process created a publicly available source of knowledge spillovers that benefited enormously the birth of the SSI with a clear commercial focus at the turn of 1980s and 1990s. At that time, several favourable environmental factors supported the industry’s evolution such as the fabulously growing PC market, the development of the Internet accompanied with the need towards secure Internet-based financial transactions. Consequently, the worldwide sales of security software products between 1997 and 2002 tripled from USD2.2 billion to USD6.9 billion (IDC Citation2000, Citation2003). Rising demand enlarged the spectrum of market supply which embraced not only basic products of encryption such as firewall or antivirus programmes, but comprehensive and advanced security services linked to protection of operating systems and applications, network security management packages, and sensible data and hardware protection (Giarratana and Fosfuri Citation2007).

The emergence of new market niches altogether with fierce market competition spurred widespread trademark issuance in SSI that enables firms to forge brand protection, to take advantage of superior product quality reputation and to forge customer loyalty, which ultimately enhances the commercialisation potential of the trademark issuer. exemplifies the various motives and applications of trademark issuance in the sector.

Table 1. SSI trademarks with the scope of application filed by prominent security software producers.

A notable technical characteristic of the industry pertains to the mathematical crypto algorithm that is the principal component of a security software product through transforming plain text data into cipher text, and what it can be strongly protected by patents. The task of crypto algorithm is to execute the encryption and decryption processes of the data, and its quality in terms of security level and speed of mathematical calculations is a decisive factor to provide competitive advantage for the owner organisation (Giarratana Citation2004). For instance, the US Patent 5,768,373 filed on 6 May 1996 by Symantec Corp. is directed towards providing a secure method to access data when the user has lost or forgotten the user password. The patent description employing several block diagrams explains that the decryption of an access key gives access to data and that two encrypted versions of the access key are created. If the password is forgotten access to data is accomplished by decrypting the second encrypted version of the access key via the private key, from the public-private key pair, which is required to be stored at a remote site. A further illustrative example is the US Patent 6,141,420 filed by Certicom Corp. on 29 January 1997 which applies an elliptic curve cryptosystem method instead of integer calculus, performing the encoding-decoding process more quickly while requiring less computer space expressed in bits (Giarratana Citation2004).

There are several industry traits that emphasise the importance of external technology search for security software manufacturers. First, product innovation plays a major role accompanied by the proliferation of lucrative new product categories (The Economist Citation2002). Second, it is a technology-based industry with continuous innovation where the complexity of a security software system requires incorporating problem solutions from distinct technological areas, for instance mathematics, hardware engineering, software development and network design (Giarratana Citation2004). Third, competition is intense implying low entry barriers, paucity of first-mover advantages for survival and a high hazard rate of firm exit (Giarratana and Fosfuri Citation2007). Therefore, I believe that the worldwide SSI proves an ideal setting to study firms’ collocation patterns of external technology search.

To verify the hypotheses, I constructed a comprehensive data set tracing SSI firms’ locations for acquisitions and strategic technology alliances on a global basis. I discovered the population of SSI organisations via security software product introduction data from Infotrac’s General Business File ASAP and PROMT database (former Predicast) that, from a large set of trade journals, magazines and other specialised press (e.g. eWeek, PC Magazine, PR Newswire, Telecomworldwire), reports several categories of events classified by industrial sectors. This data source is the more recent version of the former Predicast database and was applied in various studies (e.g. Pennings and Harianto Citation1992; Fosfuri, Giarratana, and Luzzi Citation2008). I searched for all press articles that reported a ‘Product announcement’, a ‘New software release’ and a ‘Software evaluation’ in SSI at SIC Code 73726 (Encryption Software Sector) from 1980 to 2002. These steps determined that the first product was introduced in 1989.

Prior contributions point at the pivotal role that acquisitions (Haspeslagh and Jemison Citation1991; Hitt et al. Citation1996; Pisano Citation1991; Vermeulen and Barkema Citation2001; Cassiman and Colombo Citation2006) and strategic technology alliances (Dussauge, Garrette, and Mitchell Citation2000; Hamel Citation1991; Kumar and Nti Citation1998; Lane and Lubatkin Citation1998) can play when external sources of knowledge and technology have become relevant. Therefore, I take into consideration these inter-organisational mechanisms to study ETS patterns of firms. Resorting to the same Infotrac database, I downloaded all the articles for SSI firms that report an acquisition and an alliance event under SIC 73726. For all types of events, I carefully read the text of business news, and removed the equivocal events from the sample. Considering alliance texts, I selected only those events for the variable strategic technology alliance where partners are involved in combined innovative activities or exchange of technologies (Hagedoorn and Duysters Citation2002). Hence, equivocal cases or marketing alliances were excluded. It is worth noting that acquisitions are often used to increase CEO power or to penetrate in a new and untapped geographic market (especially at older sunk-cost industries). Notwithstanding, an acquisition in SSI has primarily a technology or knowledge acquisition orientation, as target organisations can have a valuable (protected) technology or employ skilled software engineers. For instance, Cisco Systems, a firm that is heavily interested in the network, content and web security business, uses a considerable part of its profits to purchase firms with R&D capabilities (Shapiro and Varian Citation1999).

I studied all the security software firms that realised at least two external technology searches during the 3-year span 2000–2002. By this period, SSI developed into a mature industry where the use of the above two mechanisms became ubiquitous. The sample on strategic technology alliances (acquisitions) consists of 57 (51) security software firms that are undoubtedly the leading players in the industry. In constructing the database, I made firm dyads as the unit of analysis which was motivated by the following reasons: it captures a firm’s relative position, it provides a consistent comparison across organisations, and it efficiently reflects the competitive engagements of firms (Alcácer Citation2006; Baum and Korn Citation1999; Chen Citation1996; Sirmon, Gove, and Hitt Citation2008). offers descriptive statistics on the different types of ETS that the sampled firms realised across the entire study period.

Table 2. Descriptive statistics on the types of ETS.

4.2. Dependent variables

Following Alcácer’s study (Citation2006), I apply a similar measure for the construction of the dependent variable. This location index (LOCI) allows for comparing the geographic convergence or dispersion of ETS networks to any two sample firms (i and j) in giving an in-between value of complete coincidence or total dissimilarity. The sign i’ is a 1xn row vector while j denotes an nx1 column vector. Each element, of il or jl takes on either 1 or 0, depending on whether the given firm has realised an ETS activity in location l. From the viewpoint of firm i, the LOCIij measure is a percentage value of ETS locations overlapped by both firms, mathematically:

LOCIij=ijii=l=1l=niljll=1l=nilil.

The LOCI measure is dyadic by construction and varies theoretically from 0 (dispersion) to 1 (similarity). If the index reaches its maximum value 1, it means that firm j explored exactly the same geographical sites as firm i. In the reversed case, firm i and j don’t share any geographically coinciding locations in their explorative undertakings, and so the index takes the value of zero. Alcácer’s index is a quite precise and convenient way to compare the location choices of any two sample firms, as it represents a multidimensional relationship with a single value, and the interpretation is intuitive. Additionally, the index weighs only those elements that equal 1 and it is independent of the number of elements in the vectors, in contrast to correlation or covariance which ‘vary when more null elements are added to the vectors (Alcácer Citation2006, 1461)’. Ultimately, the LOCI measure inherently is not symmetric for firm pairs i-j and j-i owing to the scale applied in the denominator that is always related to the focal firm. In fact, this feature reflects competitive asymmetry (Chen Citation1996) by recording differently the presence in geographic factor markets for participants in a given firm dyad.

To calculate LOCI, first, I had to identify the exact location of all organisations with which the sample SSI firms had ETS links. For firm i, I considered the acquired firms by i, and its technology alliance partners. Second, I had to devise an appropriate policy with regard to possible geographic divisions because isolation patterns of ETS grasped by the location index might be sensitive to units of geographical classification. Let’s consider a Southern California security software maker that through locating ETS within a geographically limited territory, for example only in the neighbouring counties, might obtain increasingly higher values for LOCI compared to the same rivals if there is an increased size of geographic units. As a result, I apply a similar geographic gradation to that of Alcácer (Citation2006), for which I determine the value of LOCI for three geographic levels: clusters, countries and economic regions. Operationally, clusters are equal to US counties, or equally sized official geographic units outside of the US; country level refers to independent states or US states; and an economic region is related to a group of countries that culturally or economically share common traits. The involvement of the spatially greater regions can amplify our understanding of ETS location patterns as cluster level may overestimate the extent of geographic extension of an ETS network, assigning a biased lower value to the LOCI index. Nonethless, a cluster-level measure for LOCI can provide a more sophisticated insight of location choices because some firms may concentrate ETS to a geographically limited area.

I identified all actual geographic locations properly through the Geographic Names Information System for US locations and the Getty Thesaurus of Geographic Names for foreign, non-US locations. Finally, I calculate the LOCI value for all geographic levels considering the type of ETS activities separately (acquisition or strategic technology alliances). Consequently, I obtained six LOCI measures depending on geographic gradation and activity type. summarises the dyadic level location indices by the type of ETS activities (acquisition and strategic technology alliances) calculated at the cluster and country levels, whereas show the geographic profile of the two ETS channels at the cluster level.

Table 3. Descriptive statistics on the LOCI measure at dyadic level.

Table 4. (a) Geographic profile of ETS activities for strategic technology alliances (at the cluster level). (b) Geographic profile of ETS activities for acquisitions (at the cluster level).

4.3. Estimation procedures

I hypothesise that the location of boundary-spanning external technology search vis-à-vis rivals is generated by the function LOCIij = xTij β +ɛij, where the dependent variable is the location index for the convergence or dispersion of technology exploration networks, xij is the set of explanatory dyadic variables, β is a vector of parameters to be estimated, and ɛij is an error term. One econometric challenge involves the fact that dyadic data are assumed not to consist of independent observations, but rather have varying amounts of dependence on one another which can lead to autocorrelation in the error terms (Krackhardt Citation1988). The lack of such independence is best illustrated by a firm that purposefully decides to separate its ETS allocation from the rest of competitors due to some unknown reasons. The result introduces a chain of positive autocorrelation for all dyadic observation related to the deviating firm which can generate small standard errors and thus inflated t-statistics (Alcácer Citation2006). Additionally, the existing row or column interdependence can bias ordinary-least-squares (OLS) tests of significance (Krackhardt Citation1988). To contend with this problem of bias, I use a method based on Krackhardt (Citation1988), who proposes a nonparametric solution called the Quadratic Assignment Procedure (QAP) that provides unbiased tests for regression coefficients. The QAP algorithm proceeds by first performing an OLS regression on the original data set. Then the rows and columns of the dependent variable matrix are permuted to provide a new, scrambled matrix. The OLS regression calculation is then repeated with the new dependent variable. The programme stores coefficient estimates and R2 values. Next, another permutation of the dependent variable is drawn that is subjected to a new OLS regression whose coefficients and R-square values are again stored. This permutation-regression step is repeated 500 times that yields a reference, empirical sampling distribution for the stored betas of independent variables under the null hypothesis of no relationship between the independent variables and the dependent variable. In the end, one can compare each actual coefficient of the first OLS regression with the empirical distribution to reject the null hypothesis at an extremely high or low percentile.

4.4. Independent variables

I controlled for the generality of a firm’s upstream intellectual property right-related assets with the patentgenerality variable. Patents have been used extensively in the innovation literature to measure technological capabilities (e.g. Henderson and Cockburn Citation1994) and provide externally validated measures of innovative success that closely resonate to a firm’s level of technological competence (Narin, Noma, and Perry Citation1987). I only considered the fundamental technological classes pertaining to the SSI which include the 380, 382, 705, 709, 713 and 726 three-digit patent classes (Giarratana Citation2004). The patentgenerality variable is the Jaffe-Trajtenberg index of generality which is essentially a one minus Herfindhal index on forward citations of patents in three-digit SIC codes (Trajtenberg, Jaffe, and Hall Citation2000). By construction, it can vary between 0 and 1 (maximum portfolio generality) with high generality scores representing widespread impact in a wide range of fields (Trajtenberg, Jaffe, and Hall Citation2000). This variable is for 1998, as lagged by two years with respect to the dependent variables, and was built upon the NBER/Case Western patent database.

To grasp the downstream intellectual property right breadth of the sampled firms I resorted to the USPTO database (see De Vries et al. Citation2017; Giarratana and Fosfuri Citation2007) and downloaded exclusively the annual number of live software trademarks. To obtain only software-related trademarks for the focal organisations, I followed the method of Fosfuri, Giarratana, and Luzzi (Citation2008) in which I applied a search algorithm through strings of words to the text of the trademark description of goods and services. The second core variable, trademarkdiversification is the one minus Herfindhal index on the industrial class trademark codes from the yearly set of LIVE software trademarks of a firm. Similarly to patentgenerality, this variable is within the range 0–1 (maximum width of trademark portfolio) and lagged by two years.

To be able to test H3a and H3b, I created two multiplicative measures referred to as RRF_PATGEN*MMC and RRF_TMDIV*MMC. RRF_PATGEN and RRF_TMDIV stand for resource-rich firms in the breadth of patents and trademarks, respectively. Both are dummy variables and display 1 if the firm’s patentgenerality or trademarkdiversification value belongs to the top 33%, respectively. For robustness checks, I also created these two dummy variables considering top 10, 15% and 25% values. Results in and involve RRF variables on 10% and 33%. MMC is the abbreviation for multimarket contact, and demonstrates how many common SSI niches are shared by the two firms in a given firm dyad. The value of MMC for a firm can vary between 1 and 6, as any product launched by a security software producer can be classified into one of the six product niches: authentication digital signature, antivirus, data and hardware protection, firewalls, utility software, and network security and management (Giarratana Citation2004; Giarratana and Fosfuri Citation2007). Portfolio broadening built upon active presence in these niches is a notable product strategy in SSI (Fosfuri, Giarratana, and Sebrek Citation2018).

Table 5. Simple statistics of variables for QAP estimations.

Table 6. Results of QAP estimation (cluster and country level) for strategic technology alliances.

Table 7. Results of QAP estimation (cluster and country level) for acquisitions.

4.5. Controls

I introduce a set of controls that may be an alternate explanation for firms’ external technology search behaviour. Experience in the market is captured by the number of years a firm is competing in SSI (Age in market) where it enhances firm survival (Giarratana and Fosfuri Citation2007). This variable is the difference between a firm’s entry year and the current year. I account for any possible distortion of a firm’s scale through the variable Sales in software business which is the logarithm of the share of LIVE software trademarks on the total LIVE trademarks multiplied by the firm sales (the source of this latter: Bureau Van Dijk’s Osiris). To grasp its possible impact on the dependent variable, I inserted a subsidiary control constructed at country level that is one minus Herfindhal index on the geographic extension of sampled firms’ subsidiary locations. Higher extent of industry competition at firm entry was found to deteriorate survival options for security software makers (Giarratana and Fosfuri Citation2007). To control for different industry conditions at the time of entry I employ a measure of organisational population density at the time a firm enters the market (Density delay), as initial competition conditions can exert lasting effects on the extent of overlap in technology search locations.

Firms’ core business can influence the way ETS is spatially distanced or converged from competitors because a firm’s core sector could exhibit common patterns in searching external knowledge and technology. Moreover, SSI can also host de alio companies as implied by Giarratana (Citation2008). Hence, I employ three dummies that address the core business of the sampled organisations: Hardware (SIC code 357), Software (SIC 737), or Electronics (SIC 359-370). Data on firm core business was taken from Bureau Van Dijk’s Osiris and Hoover’s. In addition, I implement in the QAP regressions a geographical dummy that takes the value of 1 if the headquarter of a firm is situated in North America (0 otherwise). Dummies on firms’ technological background and place of origin were also introduced by Alcácer (Citation2006) in his study on subsidiary location choices.

Given that I employ a dyadic dataset, all independent and control variables similarly to the dependent variable are also dyadic: either differences from the focal firm’s perspective, or dummies with a value of 1 if both firms in a given dyad share the same feature described in the discussion of the proxy variable. To construct the database, I applied a pairing algorithm using the statistical software package R. According to the number of firms involved, the data table on which I perform the QAP regressions consist of 3192 (2550) lines for strategic technology alliances (acquisitions). To alleviate potential endogeneity problems between firm resources and locations choices of ETS, a two-year lag of independent and control variables with the location index is applied. provides the basic descriptive statistics for the independent variables and controls.

5. Results and discussion

I run regressions using Multiple Regression Quadratic Assignment Procedure with the above covariates. The dependent variable is the location index (LOCI) of external technology search whose construction varies either by ETS type or geographic unit. Models 1 and 2 of present the results of QAP estimation for strategic technology alliances on cluster and country levels. Taking into consideration the conceptualisation of the hypotheses, one must expect negative signs for the IPR-based variables of theoretical interest. The results indicate that a more general preexisting stock of industry-specific patents (patentgenerality) expands the geographic isolation of strategic technology alliances vis-à-vis rivals. Trademarkdiversification also enjoys explanatory power at strategic technology alliances causing less intensity of spatial overlap compared to rivals. Independently of the geographic units, both core variables take the expected signs, therefore corroborate H1 and H2 for strategic technology alliances.

In Model 1 and 2, the level of the resource-rich firm (RRF) dummy variables is on 33%. The multiplicative variable between resource-rich firms in the generality of patent stock and multimarket contact (RRF_PATGEN*MMC) is positive and significant both at cluster (Model 1 of ) and country level (Model 2 of ), confirming H3a for STA. This finding suggests that a high spatial overlap vis-à-vis similar resource-rich competitors in the generality of patent assets is achieved, only if both firms exhibit a high rate of multimarket contact in SSI niches. The RRF_TMDIV*MMC multiplicative variable is positive, significant at cluster but not country level which does not fully buttress H3b. Therefore, the flocking strategy of resource-rich rivals in the diversification of their trademark assets, with vast common market scope, is sensitive based on the level of geographic gradation applied. Perhaps diversification of trademarks of multipoint competitors only spurs more ETS overlap within smaller districts of a greater economic unit that result in some sort of scope economies benefits from a commercialisation point of view. These may not be obtained or may be too expensive or cost-inefficient if the range of ETS is extended. As robustness checks, Models 3 and 4 apply the 10% level for the construction of RRF variables, thus influencing the values of the multiplicative variables. Results of core variables are qualitatively unchanged.

As far as it concerns the control variables, only a few play a role in developing a geographically dispersed or concentrated ETS network in the STA sample of the Security Software Industry. The subsidiary variable proves to be negative and significant exclusively at the country level (Model 2). This suggests that a more geographically extended subsidiary network with respect to a rival (giving high value of the subsidiary control for this particular firm pair) causes divergence in STA ETS locations. Software firms with similarities in technological background exhibit an isolation pattern in STA ETS, but such an effect is observable only at cluster level with a 10% RRF level and is significant only at the margin. The multimarket contact variable is positive and significant in Models 3 and 4, and partially significant in Model 2. This implies that those security software manufacturers that exhibit high rate of multimarket contact with each other, tend to develop a geographically similar STA network. It is worth noting that the RRF dummy is negative and significant on 10% at only two cases: the RRF_PATGEN on country level in Model 4 and the RRF_TMDIV on cluster level in Model 3. This finding might indicate that resource-rich firms may aspire to flee from similar competitors. Interestingly, differences in size do not exert a significant effect on the extent of geographic convergence or divergence of STA vis-à-vis rivals.

Models 5 and 6 of present the results of QAP estimation for acquisitions on cluster and country levels. A more general preexisting stock of industry-specific patents (patentgenerality) expands the geographic isolation of acquisitions in relation to rivals. Trademarkdiversification also enjoys explanatory power at acquisitions causing less intensity of spatial overlap compared to rivals. Independently of the geographic units used for the analysis, both core variables take the expected signs which lends strong support for H1 and H2 for acquisitions.

In Model 5 and 6, the level of the resource-rich firm (RRF) dummy variables is on 33%. The multiplicative variable between resource-rich firms in the generality of patent stock and multimarket contact (RRF_PATGEN*MMC), is positive and significant both at cluster (Model 5 of ) and country level (Model 6 of ) confirming H3b. This finding suggests that a high spatial overlap at acquisitions regarding similar resource-rich competitors in the generality of patent assets is achieved, only if both firms exhibit a high rate of multimarket contact in SSI niches. The RRF_TMDIV*MMC multiplicative variable is also positive, significant on cluster and country levels, buttressing H3b. Therefore, resource-rich rivals in the diversification of their trademark assets with high market overlap follow a flocking strategy in their acquisition locations. As robustness checks, Models 7 and 8 apply the 10% level for the construction of RRF variables which demonstrates the results of core variables remain qualitatively unchanged.

With regard to the control variables, only few play a role in developing a lower or higher extent of geographic overlap in acquisition ETS locations with respect to another firm in the Security Software Industry. The multimarket contact variable is positive and significant in Models 5–8. This implies that those security software manufacturers that exhibit a high rate of multimarket contact with each other, tend to develop a geographically similar acquisition network. It is worth noting that the RRF dummy of both types is negative and significant at least on 10% through all models of . This finding indicates that resource-rich firms may aim to augment the divergence of acquisition locations from similar competitors; a notable difference in acquisition location strategy from the subpopulation of resource-rich firms with a high degree of multimarket contact. As to the other control variables, neither difference in size or in the geographic extension of subsidiary network produces a significant effect on the extent of geographic convergence or divergence of acquisitions vis-à-vis rivals.

In addition and available upon request, I examined whether the models applied in and are over-specified by the joint inclusion of IPR covariates, RRF dummy variables and these latter’s interaction with multimarket contact. Via the introduction of core covariates, and RRF variables and their interaction with MMC separately in any model, render the results unchanged.

5.1. Sensibility tests

reports a sensibility test for changes in the Location Index at cluster level. For instance, if I use coefficient estimates of Model 1 of , and make a two standard deviation increase on the mean value of patentgenerality and trademarkdiversification, the value of the location index for strategic technology alliances decreases by 38.7% and 30.4%, respectively. As a possible explanation for this finding, I conjecture that fear from reverse engineering, technological knowledge expropriation and losses of key employees by a rival’s hiring policy manifest in the patentgenerality variable. Collectively, these factors drive stronger isolation of STA network from competitors than trademarkdiversification. When repeating the same analysis on country level, the decrease in LOCI for STA is less by 7.8% for patents (equalling −30.9%), and 6% for trademarks (equalling −24.4%); understandably, firms strive more to maximise isolation when competing in a smaller geographic area.

Table 8. Sensibility test for changes in the Location Index (cluster level).

The same sensibility test shown also by was repeated with patentgenerality and trademarkdiversification for acquisitions (coefficients taken from Model 5 of ) causing a decrease in LOCI of 36% and 43.2%, respectively. As with this case, trademarkdiversification’s impact is stronger (compared with the STA sample) and I surmise that for the acquirer-searcher organisation’s commercialisation purposes, the greatest possible augmentation of acquisition location divergence from rivals leads to the best outcome. Probably, the acquirer organisation already possesses important downstream assets that might help launch the target’s technologies or products into the market. In a positive case, both parties could benefit. The acquirer can have access to key knowledge or technologies to assimilate into its own products or to the target’s products that the acquirer intends to commercialise under its own brands. In turn, the owners of the target organisation can earn profits on the sale.

I performed further sensitivity checks on the two multiplicative variables. First, I resorted to STA data from Model 1 of . If firms i and j are both resource-rich in the generality of patents (diversification of trademarks) and achieved wide market overlap, the location index of firm i with respect to firm j increases by 0.19 (0.21), 0.23 (0.26) and 0.28 (0.31) for having 4, 5 and 6 common niches, respectively. Then, I repeated the same exercise using acquisition data from Model 5 of . If firms i and j are both resource-rich in the generality of patents (diversification of trademarks) and achieved wide market overlap, the location index of firm i with respect to firm j increases by 0.38 (0.22), 0.47 (0.28) and 0.56 (0.33) for having 4, 5 and 6 common niches, respectively. I conjecture that at technology alliances, patents induce less than trademarks the flocking of multipoint resource-rich competitors due to more concerns over the efficiency of retaliation potential for knowledge leakage. Meanwhile, the reverse scenario might be true at acquisitions where patents drive more than trademarks the flocking strategy due to less expropriation concerns.

Comparing models of and through R-square values reveals that there is no significant variation introduced by the modification of the level of analysis from cluster to country. To validate the findings on core variables, I performed further unreported robustness checks by adding regions as another, more ample geographic unit, and by changing the level of RRF to 15% and 25%. Regarding these cases, the results remained broadly consistent.

6. Conclusions

According to prior contributions (Chung and Alcácer Citation2002; Kim and Kogut Citation1996; Rosenkopf and Nerkar Citation2001), this research started with the premise that external technology and knowledge search is an important mechanism for firms. Former research also discussed a strategy of self-defence from unintended knowledge spillover (Shaver and Flyer Citation2000; Alcácer and Chung Citation2007), predicting divergence of ETS from rivals. However, a varying intensity of geographic overlap in ETS channels must critically depend on firm resources. In this paper, I have investigated empirically the role of the breadth of upstream and downstream intellectual property right tools on influencing the spatial dissimilarity of ETS networks of firms compared to rivals. Notably, I studied how much firms share the extent of geographic overlap in ETS locations given the investments made in the generality of patents and the diversification of trademarks. Using the Security Software Industry as a test-bed, the empirical results suggest that the larger breadth of both IPR-based core covariates supports a lower extent of geographic overlap in external technology search compared to rivals. They play, however, somewhat different roles depending on the type of the search activity: patents buttress more than trademarks such a divergence at technology alliances, while for acquisitions the reverse mechanism prevails. Other remarkable findings are connected to resource-rich firms whose operationalisation was done separately for both patents and trademarks, and designated entities whose breadth of patents or trademarks scored highly. According to the results, a high intensity of spatial overlap vis-à-vis similar research-rich competitors is achieved, only if both firms exhibit multimarket contact in the niches of the focal industry. The findings associated with strategic technology alliances, however, are sensitive to the level of geographic gradation used.

Although there is an ample literature on open innovation, it has not been empirically linked to geographic considerations. The main contribution of my work is that I provide one of the first attempts to bring together ETS approaches and the geographic components of firm strategy. Additionally, the present study connects with a fairly recent but growing body of literature that addresses the challenges in open innovation. Specifically, earlier contributions have primarily focused on intentional knowledge leakage (Ritala et al. Citation2015), fear of imitation in absorptive capacity-rich locations (Giarratana and Mariani Citation2014), constraints on firm resources (Garriga, Von Krogh, and Spaeth Citation2013), hidden costs of openness (Cassiman and Valentini Citation2016), substantial under- or over-performance (Alexy, Bascavusoglu-Moreau, and Salter Citation2016), and negative internal attitudes (de Araújo Burcharth, Knudsen, and Sondergaard Citation2014). My study discloses an additional challenge for firms to conduct effective ETS against rivals in the face of the breadth of IPR resources. This research adds some empirical contributions, too. First, a notable trait of this study is that it jointly involves acquisitions and strategic technology alliances as crucial external knowledge and technology sources for business organisations. Second, in observance to the research line hallmarked by contributions from Block et al. (Citation2015), Fosfuri, Giarratana, and Luzzi (Citation2008), Fosfuri and Giarratana (Citation2009) and Mendonça, Santos Pereira and Godinho (Citation2004) that promote trademarks as strategic assets, this study focuses on the diversity dimension offering a value addition.

The findings of this study offer several implications for management practise. The general message of this paper for practising managers is that firms having broad IPR-related resources can be better positioned in the quest for external knowledge and technology. It is an important factor to have in mind as there is strong competition for external partners that can be located in distinct geographical areas. Firms better equipped with a large breadth of key IPR assets can themselves set the pace of competition that eventually crowds out rivals from crucial technology input factor markets. The results stress the indispensable role of internal IPR policy for firms to be able to approach partners that might have a different knowledge background. This is underpinned by the meaningful impact of patent generality which might motivate senior management to develop a suitable portfolio with a more ample spectrum. In addition, the study also highlights how a diversified trademark portfolio can buttress a competitive advantage at ETS contests against rivals in an innovative setting. Its implication for management practise refers to boosting organisational ability to produce a portfolio of trademarks with a diversified nature. One option is by hiring trademark experts that can shorten the IPR-grant process whereby promoting external technology search. Last, managers of resource-rich entities should not necessarily worry about knowledge spillovers by their resource-rich rivals as flocking with them in ETS locations occurs solely in case of multimarket contacts in the niches of the industry. Specifically, when fear of negative spillover balance is of concern, effective managers should put more emphasis on conscious efforts against knowledge expropriation, for instance through secrecy or the practise of mutual forbearance with retaliation potential.

This study also sends important messages for policymakers. For instance, richer firms in terms of the breadth of IPR resources tend to source technical diversity through various channels of ETS in which they are willing to make a widespread geographical exploration. This is a good piece of news for economic decision-makers of technologically laggard regions. If those regions are developed with an appropriate economic policy, the opportunity to nurture local firms with specialised expertise will be created. Sooner or later these local enterprises can connect with and potentially assimilate into a broad industrial network. The beneficial outcome will be increased profits via new business opportunities with a larger community of firms.

This study is not exempt from limitations. The single-industry nature of data (with limited technology focus) applied in the analyses demands the results are examined in other technology-based contexts. However, characteristics of the Security Software Industry like the overall focus on product innovation, the fierce nature of competition and the product complexity of security software systems (Giarratana Citation2004) can easily compare to other young and technology-based environments. Further limitations stem from the relatively short time window of the current study which could be widened and thus improved in the future research.

Acknowledgments

The author is grateful to Joern H. Block (special issue coeditor) and two anonymous reviewers for their excellent guidance and feedback. My appreciation also goes to Juan Alcácer, Marco S. Giarratana, Keld Laursen, Toke Reichstein, and seminar participants at the 2018 annual European Academy of Management Conference (Iceland) that have commented on earlier drafts. I also thank Betsabé Perez Garrido for computational assistance and Gregory De La Piedra for language assistance. I gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Hungarian National Research, Development and Innovation Office (PD16-121037).

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by the Hungarian National Research, Development and Innovation Office [PD16-121037].

References

  • Aaker, D. A. 1991. Managing Brand Equity: Capitalizing on the Value of a Brand. New York: Free Press.
  • Alcácer, J. 2006. “Location Choices across the Value Chain: How Activity and Capability Influence Collocation.” Management Science 52 (10): 1457–1471. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1060.0658.
  • Alcácer, J., and W. Chung. 2007. “Location Strategies and Knowledge Spillovers.” Management Science 53 (5): 760–776. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1060.0637.
  • Alexy, O., E. Bascavusoglu-Moreau, and A. J. Salter. 2016. “Toward an Aspiration-Level Theory of Open Innovation.” Industrial and Corporate Change 25 (2): 289–306. doi:10.1093/icc/dtw003.
  • Almeida, P., and B. Kogut. 1999. “Localization of Knowledge and the Mobility of Engineers in Regional Networks.” Management Science 45 (7): 905–917. doi:10.1287/mnsc.45.7.905.
  • Arora, A., and M. Ceccagnoli. 2006. “Patent Protection, Complementary Assets, and Firms’ Incentives for Technology Licensing.” Management Science 52 (2): 293–308. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1050.0437.
  • Barney, J. B. 1991. “Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage.” Journal of Management 17 (1): 99–120. doi:10.1177/014920639101700108.
  • Barroso, A., and M. S. Giarratana. 2013. “Product Proliferation Strategies and Firm Performance: The Moderating Role of Product Space Complexity.” Strategic Management Journal 34 (12): 1435–1452. doi:10.1002/smj.2013.34.issue-12.
  • Baum, J. A. C., and H. J. Korn. 1999. “Dynamics of Dyadic Competitive Interaction.” Strategic Management Journal 20 (3): 251–278. doi:10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(199903)20:3<251::AID-SMJ23>3.0.CO;2-H.
  • Bernheim, B. D., and M. D. Whinston. 1990. “Multimarket Contact and Collusive Behavior.” The RAND Journal of Economics 21 (1): 1–26. doi:10.2307/2555490.
  • Blind, K., J. Edler, R. Frietsch, and U. Schmoch. 2006. “Motives to Patent: Empirical Evidence from Germany.” Research Policy 35 (5): 655–672. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2006.03.002.
  • Block, J. H., G. De Vries, J. H. Schumann, and P. Sandner. 2014. “Trademarks and Venture Capital Valuation.” Journal of Business Venturing 29 (4): 525–542. doi:10.1016/j.jbusvent.2013.07.006.
  • Block, J. H., C. O. Fisch, A. Hahn, and P. G. Sandner. 2015. “Why Do SMEs File Trademarks? Insights from Firms in Innovative Industries.” Research Policy 44 (10): 1915–1930. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2015.06.007.
  • Boeker, W., J. Goodstein, J. Stephan, and J. P. Murmann. 1997. “Competition in a Multimarket Environment: The Case of Market Exit.” Organization Science 8 (2): 126–142. doi:10.1287/orsc.8.2.126.
  • Cantwell, J. 1989. Technological Innovation and Multinational Corporations. Oxford, UK: Basil Blackwell.
  • Cantwell, J., and O. Janne. 1999. “Technological Globalisation and Innovative Centres: The Role of Corporate Technological Leadership and Locational Hierarchy.” Research Policy 28 (2–3): 119–144. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(98)00118-8.
  • Carroll, G. R., and A. Swaminathan. 2000. “Why the Microbrewery Movement? Organizational Dynamics of Resource Partitioning in the U.S. Brewing Industry.” American Journal of Sociology 106 (3): 715–762. doi:10.1086/318962.
  • Cassiman, B., and M. G. Colombo, Eds. 2006. Mergers & Acquisitions: The Innovation Impact. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.
  • Cassiman, B., and G. Valentini. 2016. “Open Innovation: Are Inbound and Outbound Knowledge Flows Really Complementary?” Strategic Management Journal 37 (6): 1034–1046. doi:10.1002/smj.2375.
  • Cassiman, B., and R. Veugelers. 2002. “R&D Cooperation and Spillovers: Some Empirical Evidence from Belgium.” American Economic Review 92 (4): 1169–1184. doi:10.1257/00028280260344704.
  • Castanias, R. P., and C. E. Helfat. 1991. “Managerial Resources and Rents.” Journal of Management 17 (1): 155–171. doi:10.1177/014920639101700110.
  • Chen, M.-J. 1996. “Competitor Analysis and Interfirm Rivalry: Toward a Theoretical Integration.” Academy of Management Review 21 (1): 100–134. doi:10.5465/amr.1996.9602161567.
  • Chung, W., and J. Alcácer. 2002. “Knowledge Seeking and Location Choice of Foreign Direct Investment in the United States.” Management Science 48 (12): 1534–1554. doi:10.1287/mnsc.48.12.1534.440.
  • Cohen, D. 1991. “Trademark Strategy Revisited.” The Journal of Marketing 55 (3): 46–59. doi:10.1177/002224299105500305.
  • Cohen, W. M., and S. Klepper. 1996. “A Reprise of Size and R&D.” The Economic Journal 106 (437): 925–951. doi:10.2307/2235365.
  • Dahlander, L., and D. M. Gann. 2010. “How Open Is Innovation?” Research Policy 39 (6): 699–709. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2010.01.013.
  • de Araújo Burcharth, A. L., M. P. Knudsen, and H. A. Søndergaard. 2014. “Neither Invented nor Shared Here: The Impact and Management of Attitudes for the Adoption of Open Innovation Practices.” Technovation 34 (3): 149–161. doi:10.1016/j.technovation.2013.11.007.
  • De Vries, G., E. Pennings, J. H. Block, and C. Fisch. 2017. “Trademark or Patent? the Effects of Market Concentration, Customer Type and Venture Capital Financing on Start-Ups’ Initial IP Applications.” Industry and Innovation 24 (4): 325–345. doi:10.1080/13662716.2016.1231607.
  • Dobrev, S. D., T. Y. Kim, and G. R. Carroll. 2002. “The Evolution of Organizational Niches: US Automobile Manufacturers, 1885–1981.” Administrative Science Quarterly 47 (2): 233–264. doi:10.2307/3094805.
  • Dodgson, M., Ed. 1989. Technological Strategy and the Firm: Management and Public Policy. London: Longman.
  • Dowell, G. 2006. “Product Line Strategies of New Entrants in an Established Industry: Evidence from the US Bicycle Industry.” Strategic Management Journal 27 (10): 959–979. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Dussauge, P., B. Garrette, and W. Mitchell. 2000. “Learning from Competing Partners: Outcomes and Durations of Scale and Link Alliances in Europe, North America and Asia.” Strategic Management Journal 21 (2): 99–126. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • The Economist. 2002. A Survey of Digital Security: Securing the Cloud. October 26.
  • Escribano, A., A. Fosfuri, and J. A. Tribo. 2009. “Managing External Knowledge Flows: The Moderating Role of Absorptive Capacity.” Research Policy 38 (1): 96–105. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2008.10.022.
  • Flikkema, M., A. P. De Man, and C. Castaldi. 2014. “Are Trademark Counts a Valid Indicator of Innovation? Results of an In-Depth Study of New Benelux Trademarks Filed by SMEs.” Industry and Innovation 21 (4): 310–331. doi:10.1080/13662716.2014.934547.
  • Forman, C., A. Goldfarb, and S. Greenstein. 2008. “Understanding the Inputs into Innovation: Do Cities Substitute for Internal Firm Resources?” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 17 (2): 295–316. doi:10.1111/j.1530-9134.2008.00179.x.
  • Fosfuri, A., and M. S. Giarratana. 2009. “Masters of War: Rivals’ Product Innovation and New Advertising in Mature Product Markets.” Management Science 55 (2): 181–191. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1080.0939.
  • Fosfuri, A., M. S. Giarratana, and A. Luzzi. 2008. “The Penguin Has Entered the Building: The Commercialization of Open Source Software Products.” Organization Science 19 (2): 292–305. doi:10.1287/orsc.1070.0321.
  • Fosfuri, A., M. S. Giarratana, and S. S. Sebrek. 2018. “Resource Partitioning and Strategies in Markets for Technology.” Strategic Organization. doi:10.1177/1476127018791329.
  • Gandal, N., S. Markovich, and M. Riordan. 2005. “Ain’t it “Suite”? Bundling in the PC Office Software Market.” Unpublished manuscript.
  • Gans, J. S., and S. Stern. 2003. “The Product Market and the Market for “Ideas”: Commercialization Strategies for Technology Entrepreneurs.” Research Policy 32 (2): 333–350. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(02)00103-8.
  • Gao, G., and L. M. Hitt. 2012. “Information Technology and Trademarks: Implications for Product Variety.” Management Science 58 (6): 1211–1226. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1110.1480.
  • Garriga, H., G. Von Krogh, and S. Spaeth. 2013. “How Constraints and Knowledge Impact Open Innovation.” Strategic Management Journal 34 (9): 1134–1144. doi:10.1002/smj.2013.34.issue-9.
  • Garud, R., and A. Kumaraswamy. 1993. “Changing Competitive Dynamics in Network Industries: An Exploration of Sun Microsystems‘ Open Systems Strategy.” Strategic Management Journal 14 (5): 351–369. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Giarratana, M. S. 2004. “The Birth of a New Industry: Entry by Startups and the Drivers of Firm Growth. The Case of Encryption Software.” Research Policy 33 (5): 787–806. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2004.01.001.
  • Giarratana, M. S. 2008. “Missing the Starting Gun: De Alio Entry Order in New Markets, Inertia and Real Option Capabilities.” European Management Review 5 (2): 115–124. doi:10.1057/emr.2008.7.
  • Giarratana, M. S., and A. Fosfuri. 2007. “Product Strategies and Survival in Schumpeterian Environments: Evidence from the US Security Software Industry.” Organization Studies 28 (6): 909–929. doi:10.1177/0170840607075267.
  • Giarratana, M. S., and M. Mariani. 2014. “The Relationship between Knowledge Sourcing and Fear of Imitation.” Strategic Management Journal 35 (8): 1144–1163. doi:10.1002/smj.2014.35.issue-8.
  • Giarratana, M. S., and S. Torrisi. 2010. “Foreign Entry and Survival in a Knowledge‐Intensive Market: Emerging Economy Countries’ International Linkages, Technology Competences, and Firm Experience.” Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 4 (1): 85–104. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1932-443X.
  • Hagedoorn, J., and G. Duysters. 2002. “External Sources of Innovative Capabilities: The Preferences for Strategic Alliances or Mergers and Acquisitions.” Journal of Management Studies 39 (2): 167–188. doi:10.1111/joms.2002.39.issue-2.
  • Hall, B. H., and R. H. Ziedonis. 2001. “The Patent Paradox Revisited: An Empirical Study of Patenting in the U.S. Semiconductor Industry 1979–1995.” The RAND Journal of Economics 32 (1): 101–128. doi:10.2307/2696400.
  • Hamel, G. 1991. “Competition for Competence and Inter-Partner Learning within International Strategic Alliances.” Strategic Management Journal 12 (S1): 83–103. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Haspeslagh, P., and D. Jemison. 1991. Managing Acquisitions: Creating Value Through Corporate Renewal. New York: Free Press.
  • Helmers, C., and M. Rogers. 2010. “Innovation and the Survival of New Firms in the UK.” Review of Industrial Organization 36 (3): 227–248. doi:10.1007/s11151-010-9247-7.
  • Henderson, R., and I. Cockburn. 1994. “Measuring Competence? Exploring Firm Effects in Pharmaceutical Research.” Strategic Management Journal 15 (S1): 63–84. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Hitt, M. A., R. E. Hoskisson, R. A. Johnson, and D. D. Moesel. 1996. “The Market for Corporate Control and Firm Innovation.” Academy of Management Journal 39 (5): 1084–1119.
  • International Data Corporation (IDC). 2000. Security Software Market Analysis. Annual Report.
  • International Data Corporation (IDC). 2003. Security Software Market Analysis. Annual Report.
  • Jaffe, A., M. Trajtenberg, and R. Henderson. 1993. “Geographic Localization of Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3): 577–598. doi:10.2307/2118401.
  • Kapferer, J.-N. 1997. Strategic Brand Management: Creating and Sustaining Brand Equity Long Term. London: Kogan Page.
  • Karnani, A., and B. Wernerfelt. 1985. “Multiple Point Competition.” Strategic Management Journal 6 (1): 87–96. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Kim, D.-J., and B. Kogut. 1996. “Technological Platforms and Diversification.” Organization Science 7 (3): 283–301. doi:10.1287/orsc.7.3.283.
  • King, A. A., and C. L. Tucci. 2002. “Incumbent Entry into New Market Niches: The Role of Experience and Managerial Choice in the Creation of Dynamic Capabilities.” Management Science 48 (2): 171–186. doi:10.1287/mnsc.48.2.171.253.
  • Kogut, B., and U. Zander. 1992. “Knowledge of the Firm, Combinative Capabilities, and the Replication of Technology.” Organization Science 3 (3): 383–397. doi:10.1287/orsc.3.3.383.
  • Krackhardt, D. 1988. “Predicting with Networks: Nonparametric Multiple Regression Analysis of Dyadic Data.” Social Networks 10 (4): 359–381. doi:10.1016/0378-8733(88)90004-4.
  • Krasnikov, A., S. Mishra, and D. Orozco. 2009. “Evaluating the Financial Impact of Branding Using Trademarks: A Framework and Empirical Evidence.” Journal of Marketing 73 (6): 154–166. doi:10.1509/jmkg.73.6.154.
  • Kumar, R., and K. O. Nti. 1998. “Differential Learning and Interaction in Alliance Dynamics: A Process and Outcome Discrepancy Model.” Organization Science 9 (3): 356–367. doi:10.1287/orsc.9.3.356.
  • Lancaster, K. 1984. “Brand Advertising Competition and Industry Demand.” Journal of Advertising 13 (4): 19–30. doi:10.1080/00913367.1984.10672913.
  • Lancaster, K. 1990. “The Economics of Product Variety: A Survey.” Marketing Science 9 (3): 189–206. doi:10.1287/mksc.9.3.189.
  • Lane, P. J., and M. Lubatkin. 1998. “Relative Absorptive Capacity and Interorganizational Learning.” Strategic Management Journal 19 (5): 461–477. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • le Duc, N., and J. Lindeque. 2018. “Proximity and Multinational Enterprise Co-Location in Clusters: A Multiple Case Study of Dutch Science Parks.” Industry and Innovation 25 (3): 282–307. doi:10.1080/13662716.2017.1355230.
  • Li, S. X., and R. Greenwood. 2004. “The Effect of Within-Industry Diversification on Firm Performance: Synergy Creation, Multi-Market Contact and Market Structuration.” Strategic Management Journal 25 (12): 1131–1153. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Mendonça, S., T. Santos Pereira, and M. M. Godinho. 2004. “Trademarks as an Indicator of Innovation and Industrial Change.” Research Policy 33 (9): 1385–1404. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2004.09.005.
  • Narin, F., E. Noma, and R. Perry. 1987. “Patents as Indicators of Corporate Technological Strength.” Research Policy 16 (2–4): 143–155. doi:10.1016/0048-7333(87)90028-X.
  • Negro, G., F. Visentin, and A. Swaminathan. 2014. “Resource Partitioning and the Organizational Dynamics of ‘Fringe Banking’.” American Sociological Review 79 (4): 680–704. doi:10.1177/0003122414537644.
  • Pennings, J. M., and F. Harianto. 1992. “The Diffusion of Technological Innovation in the Commercial Banking Industry.” Strategic Management Journal 13 (1): 29–46. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Pisano, G. P. 1991. “The Governance of Innovation: Vertical Integration and Collaborative Arrangements in the Biotechnology Industry.” Research Policy 20 (3): 237–249. doi:10.1016/0048-7333(91)90054-T.
  • Reuer, J. J., and N. Lahiri. 2013. “Searching for Alliance Partners: Effects of Geographic Distance on the Formation of R&D Collaborations.” Organization Science 25 (1): 283–298. doi:10.1287/orsc.1120.0805.
  • Ritala, P., H. Olander, S. Michailova, and K. Husted. 2015. “Knowledge Sharing, Knowledge Leaking and Relative Innovation Performance: An Empirical Study.” Technovation 35: 22–31. doi:10.1016/j.technovation.2014.07.011.
  • Rosenkopf, L., and A. Nerkar. 1999. “On the Complexity of Technological Evolution: Exploring Coevolution within and across Hierarchical Levels in Optical Disc Technology.” In Variations in Organization Science: In Honor of D. T. Campbell, edited by J. A. C. Baum and W. McKelvey, 169–183. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
  • Rosenkopf, L., and A. Nerkar. 2001. “Beyond Local Search: Boundary-Spanning, Exploration, and Impact in the Optical Disk Industry.” Strategic Management Journal 22 (4): 287–306. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Rosenkopf, L., and M. L. Tushman. 1998. “The Coevolution of Community Networks and Technology: Lessons from the Flight Simulation Industry.” Industrial and Corporate Change 7 (2): 311–346. doi:10.1093/icc/7.2.311.
  • Sakkab, N. Y. 2002. “Connect & Develop Complements Research & Develop at P&G.” Research Technology Management 45 (2): 38–45. doi:10.1080/08956308.2002.11671490.
  • Salge, T. O., T. Farchi, M. I. Barrett, and S. Dopson. 2013. “When Does Search Openness Really Matter? A Contingency Study of Health-Care Innovation Projects.” Journal of Product Innovation Management 30 (4): 659–676. doi:10.1111/jpim.2013.30.issue-4.
  • Sandner, P. G., and J. Block. 2011. “The Market Value of R&D, Patents, and Trademarks.” Research Policy 40 (7): 969–985. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2011.04.004.
  • Saxenian, A. 1994. Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Cambridge, USA: Harvard University Press.
  • Seethamraju, C. 2003. “The Value Relevance of Trademarks.” In Intangible Assets: Values. Measures and Risks, edited by J. R. M. Hand and B. Lev, 228–247. New York: Oxford University Press.
  • Shapiro, C., and H. R. Varian. 1999. Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
  • Shaver, J. M., and F. Flyer. 2000. “Agglomeration Economies, Firm Heterogeneity, and Foreign Direct Investment in the United States.” Strategic Management Journal 21 (12): 1175–1193. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Siggelkow, N. 2003. “Why Focus? A Study of Intra-Industry Focus Effects.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 51 (2): 121–150. doi:10.1111/1467-6451.00195.
  • Sirmon, D. G., S. Gove, and M. A. Hitt. 2008. “Resource Management in Dyadic Competitive Rivalry: The Effects of Resource Bundling and Deployment.” Academy of Management Journal 51 (5): 919–935. doi:10.5465/amj.2008.34789656.
  • Smith, G. V., and R. L. Parr. 2000. Valuation of Intellectual Property and Intangible Assets. 3rd ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
  • Sorenson, O. 2000. “Letting the Market Work for You: An Evolutionary Perspective on Product Strategy.” Strategic Management Journal 21 (5): 577–592. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Sorenson, O., S. McEvily, C. R. Ren, and R. Roy. 2006. “Niche Width Revisited: Organizational Scope, Behavior and Performance.” Strategic Management Journal 27 (10): 915–936. doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1097-0266.
  • Strumsky, D., and J. Lobo. 2015. “Identifying the Sources of Technological Novelty in the Process of Invention.” Research Policy 44 (8): 1445–1461. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2015.05.008.
  • Swaminathan, A. 2001. “Resource Partitioning and the Evolution of Specialist Organizations: The Role of Location and Identity in the U.S. Wine Industry.” Academy of Management Journal 44 (6): 1169–1185.
  • Teece, D. 1986. “Profiting from Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy.” Research Policy 15 (6): 285–305. doi:10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2.
  • Trajtenberg, M., A. Jaffe, and B. Hall. 2000. “The NBER/Case Western Patents Data File: A Guided Tour.” Unpublished manuscript.
  • Tripsas, M. 1997. “Unraveling the Process of Creative Destruction: Complementary Assets and Incumbent Survival in the Typesetter Industry.” Strategic Management Journal 19 (S1): 119–142.
  • Veer, T., and F. Jell. 2012. “Contributing to Markets for Technology? A Comparison of Patent Filing Motives of Individual Inventors, Small Companies and Universities.” Technovation 32 (9–10): 513–522. doi:10.1016/j.technovation.2012.03.002.
  • Vermeulen, F., and H. Barkema. 2001. “Learning through Acquisitions.” Academy of Management Journal 44 (3): 457–476.
  • Warlop, L., S. Ratneshwar, and S. M. J. Van Osselaer. 2005. “Distinctive Brand Cues and Memory for Product Consumption Experiences.” International Journal of Research in Marketing 22 (1): 27–44. doi:10.1016/j.ijresmar.2004.02.001.
  • Zahavi, T., and D. Lavie. 2013. “Intra-Industry Diversification and Firm Performance.” Strategic Management Journal 34 (8): 978–998. doi:10.1002/smj.2013.34.issue-8.
  • Zahra, S. A., and G. George. 2002. “Absorptive Capacity: A Review, Re-Conceptualization, and Extension.” Academy of Management Journal 27 (2): 185–203.
  • Zhou, H., P. G. Sandner, S. L. Martinelli, and J. H. Block. 2016. “Patents, Trademarks, and Their Complementarity in Venture Capital Funding.” Technovation 47: 14–22. doi:10.1016/j.technovation.2015.11.005.
  • Ziedonis, R. H. 2004. “Don’t Fence Me In: Fragmented Markets for Technology and the Patent Acquisition Strategies of Firms.” Management Science 50 (6): 804–820. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1040.0208.
  • Zobel, A. K., B. Balsmeier, and H. Chesbrough. 2016. “Does Patenting Help or Hinder Open Innovation? Evidence from New Entrants in the Solar Industry.” Industrial and Corporate Change 25 (2): 307–331. doi:10.1093/icc/dtw005.
  • Zollo, M., and S. G. Winter. 2002. “Deliberate Learning and the Evolution of Dynamic Capabilities.” Organization Science 13 (3): 339–351. doi:10.1287/orsc.13.3.339.2780.