4,464
Views
1
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Demand pull or supply push? Metro-level analysis of start-ups in the United States

&
Pages 232-246 | Received 28 Feb 2017, Accepted 12 Sep 2017, Published online: 26 Oct 2017

Abstract

This paper examines factors related to higher regional start-up activity. Two hypotheses are formulated to explain start-ups: the demand-pull hypothesis argues that the amount, growth and density of aggregate demand will stimulate start-ups in any sectors; and the supply-push hypothesis argues that factors including high-tech industry concentrations, patent generation, industrial and university research activities, and government funding will stimulate high-tech start-ups. Both hypotheses support the importance of human capital factors, such as a highly educated or skilled workforce and thick labour markets. The paper incorporates these various measures and employs cross-sectional multivariate analysis of start-up rates in all sectors and in high-tech sectors in 366 metropolitan areas as defined by the US Census Bureau in 2009. Overall, very strong support is found for the demand-pull hypothesis, but only modest support for the supply-push hypothesis, which provide substantial caveats for public policy to promote start-up activities.

JEL Classifications:

Introduction

Entrepreneurship is an important element in regional economic development because it is a fundamental driver of the economy. Long ago, Schumpeter (Citation1926, Citation1950) argued that the source of economic development is entrepreneurs who bring about creative destruction. More recently, Fritsch (Citation2008) elaborated four economic functions of entrepreneurship: (1) improving efficiency by competing with existing companies; (2) providing a greater variety of goods and services; (3) amplifying innovations by creating new markets; and (4) accelerating industrial and structural change. In this paper we study two indicators of entrepreneurship across US regions: the overall business start-up rate and the high-tech business start-up rate. We amplify Fritsch’s second and third points: business starts across all sectors could provide greater variety of commodities within metropolitan areas, whereas start-ups with significant growth potential could implement innovations and create new external markets. Start-ups in high-tech sectors are considered more likely to be innovative than the typical new firm (Acs & Armington, Citation2006; Acs, Audretsch, & Lehmann, Citation2013).

We also have empirical evidence to observe the impact of start-ups thanks to recent advances in microeconomic data. Based on Longitudinal Establishment and Enterprise Microdata (Acs & Armington, Citation2006) and Business Dynamics Statistics (Haltiwanger, Citation2012; Haltiwanger, Jarmin, & Miranda, Citation2013), young companies, particularly those under five years of age, are the ‘net’ job creators after calculating both job creation and job destruction.Footnote1 Other studies investigate whether entrepreneurship has generated employment growth at the regional level (Acs & Armington, Citation2006; Ashcroft & Love, Citation1996; Fritsch & Mueller, Citation2008; Stephens, Partridge, & Faggian, Citation2013). Given this empirical evidence, it would be interesting to examine the variation of start-up rates for all metropolitan areas in the United States.

We employ Business Dynamics Statistics and National Establishment Time-Series (NETS) data and extend the analysis to examine regional factors behind variation in start-up rates. By reviewing knowledge spillover theory and agglomeration theory, we conduct a systematic examination to extract and integrate the major factors of these two different conceptualizations, which leads to supply-push and demand-pull hypotheses. The supply-push hypothesis builds on knowledge spillover from research universities and high-tech sectors, while the demand-pull hypothesis emphasizes aggregate demand based on the size and growth of the population and market. Most factors pertain to one of these hypotheses, but some pertain to both. To examine the demand-pull hypothesis, we test start-up rates in all sectors; for the supply-push hypothesis, we examine start-up rates in high-tech sectors only. We employ cross-sectional multivariate analysis for all 366 metropolitan areas as defined by the US Census Bureau in 2009. Finally, we interpret the results and offer suggestions for future research that could inform entrepreneurship-related public policy.

LITERATURE REVIEW AND FRAMEWORK

Two major schools of thought explain the variations of entrepreneurship rates at the metropolitan level. While some overlap exists, each school has a distinct scope of inputs and outputs concerning entrepreneurship. We review each school closely in this section: knowledge spillover theory and agglomeration theory, and identify three sets of factors worth analyzing.

Knowledge spillover theory

Current consideration of the regional variation in entrepreneurship rates comes from the literature on knowledge spillovers (Acs & Armington, Citation2006; Acs et al., Citation2013; Doran, McCarthy, & O’Connor, Citation2016; Fritsch, Citation2002). The roots of this literature go back over two decades. Based on higher observed research productivity and citations, Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Henderson (Citation1993) and Jaffe, Fogarty, and Banks (Citation1998), as well as Griliches (Citation1992), argued that researchers benefit from the proximity of other researchers, thereby realizing knowledge spillovers within geographically proximate areas. Subsequent studies focused on the inputs required for research and innovation-intensive activities and modelled various forms of private corporate and university research activities, commercial applications of new knowledge (i.e., patents), and highly skilled and tech-oriented human capital (Anselin, Varga, & Acs, Citation1997; Arauzo-Carod & Manjón-Antolín, Citation2012; Audretsch, Hülsbeck, & Lehmann, Citation2012; Feldman & Florida, Citation1994; McCann, Citation2007; Simon & Nardinelli, Citation2002).

An underlying assumption of knowledge spillover theory applications is that high-tech firms primarily represent growth entrepreneurship, that is, innovative firms with significant growth potential (Acs & Armington, Citation2006; Acs et al., Citation2013). These high-tech start-ups then should be influenced by specialized inputs in the knowledge production function. Important factors include the concentration of existing high-tech industries, often measured with location quotients (LQs), the level of patent production, regional research activity, primarily research at area universities, and the amount and concentration of skilled human capital. Furthermore, it is not just the presence of skilled labour but the mechanism by which knowledge spills over when workers move between jobs and industries, taking their accumulated skills and tacit knowledge with them (Audretsch & Feldman, Citation2004). Moretti (Citation2012) identified this mechanism operating in ‘thick’ labour markets. This literature identifies candidate supply-push factors that may generate start-ups.

Considering knowledge spillover theory, we note that some studies of entrepreneurship overvalue high-tech sectors and undervalue agglomeration. In fact, empirical evidence suggests that the growth of employment or productivity in high-tech sectors has been slower than the overall economy since the 1990s (Hecker, Citation2005; Kask & Sieber, Citation2002). Furthermore, among high-growth companies, high-tech sectors comprise less than one-quarter (Brown & Mason, Citation2017; Motoyama, Citation2015). Thus, we examine entrepreneurship across all sectors of the economy and move to the second school of thought that considers agglomeration economies, which affect external economies of urbanization and localization.

Agglomeration, urbanization and localization

Agglomeration economies are observed in metropolitan areas, enhancing innovation and productivity, as city size and density increase (Alañón-Pardo & Arauzo-Carod, Citation2013; Duranton & Kerr, Citation2015; Hindle, Citation2010; Jofre-Monseny, Marín-López, & Viladecans-Marsal, Citation2011; Puga, Citation2010; Sedgley & Elmslie, Citation2004). Two influential works in the mid-20th century narrowed the focus to localization economies. First, Losch (Citation1954) deeply examined localization economies, which are external to a firm but internal to an industry within a geographical region. Second, Chinitz (Citation1961) added the importance of industrial structure and dominance, which sparked a series of studies to test the effect on aggregate regional growth of the region’s average firm size (Drucker, Citation2011; Drucker & Feser, Citation2012; Evans, Citation1986; Norton, Citation1992) and the diversity of regional industries (Glaeser, Kallal, Scheinkman, & Shleifer, Citation1992; Henderson, Citation1986, Citation2003). These studies of localization economies have led to the continuing interest in industry clusters as the major focus of local economic development practice in the United States (Porter, Citation1998). Yet fundamental aspects of urbanization economies have received less attention, at times treated as control variables in empirical work.

We embrace the classic work of Alfred Marshall and recognize the benefits of co-location that enable sharing pools of highly skilled labour, customers, specialized suppliers and ancillary services (Marshall, Citation1898, pp. 346–356). In addition to the diversity of skill sets that large pools of labour offer, Marshall also emphasized the potential heterogeneity of aggregate demand that large markets offer. As population grows, more highly differentiated markets provide opportunities for new businesses to serve new market niches; it is not just the sheer size or the composition of industry that matter. Aggregate demand grows with market size and has the power to spark entrepreneurship in the regional economy. These demand-pull factors address the drivers of start-ups in all sectors. Here, urbanization economies that increase with the size, growth and density of the local market are expected to be most influential, emphasizing the importance of aggregate market demand on start-up rates. Jacobs (Citation1961, p. 151) placed special emphasis on density arguing that higher density ‘created effective economic pools’. An important assumption here is that most of these start-ups will serve the local market, and therefore the survivors will have growth potential limited by the size of the local market.

Both schools of thought reference factors related to skilled human capital either as part of the knowledge production function or as augmenting agglomeration economies.

Finally, a related set of studies noted the roles of foreign-born immigrants because they have higher rates of entrepreneurship than the native population. Literature exists about ethnic enclaves (Waldinger, Citation1986; Waldinger, Aldrich, & Ward, Citation1990), high-skill immigrants in Silicon Valley (Saxenian, Citation1999, Citation2006), and inclusion of immigrants in the entrepreneurial index (Fairie, Citation2010, Citation2014). Foreign-born workers also contribute to the skilled workforce in Silicon Valley (Saxenian, Motoyama, & Quan, Citation2002).

Examining the two hypotheses about start-up activities based on these two schools of thought is important for several reasons. First, the results will help us understand whether supply-push factors that may be associated with high-tech start-ups are also associated with the start-up rate in all sectors. We need to keep mind that not all metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) have significant economic activity in high-tech sectors. Will we find that supply-push factors are associated with start-up activities in all sectors, high-tech and non-high-tech alike? Second, the currently dominant practice relies heavily on supply-push factors assuming they will promote entrepreneurship. For example, the federal government funds research and development (R&D) through the National Institute of Health (NIH) and Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) programmes (Audretsch, Link, & Scott, Citation2002; Cooper, Citation2003; Deaton, Citation2003; Lerner, Citation2000). Research universities generate cutting-edge technologies, develop science parks and establish technology-transfer offices to commercialize basic science (Degroof & Roberts, Citation2004; Mayer, Citation2007; Plosila, Citation2004; Sa, Geiger, & Hallacher, Citation2008). Patents and licences are often used to measure such bridging activities (AUTM, Citation2012, Citation2016). An important initial question is: are supply-push factors correlated with start-up rates?

MEASURES AND DATA SOURCES

Two dependent variables help test the two schools of thoughts discussed above: the start-up rate pertaining to businesses in all sectors and the start-up rate in high-tech sectors. The high-tech sectors here include information and communication technology (ICT), health and life sciences technology, and advanced manufacturing. As noted, we expect that new firms primarily serving the local market will dominate start-up rates in all sectors. High-tech businesses are more likely to incorporate innovations that generate products traded in larger markets outside the metropolitan area. Knowledge spillover theory suggests that these new firms have strong growth potential (growth entrepreneurship) and are likely to become part of the metropolitan area’s export base.Footnote2

The following 10 factors serve as the explanatory variables drawn directly from the literatures cited above:

Supply-push: knowledge spillovers, research activity and high-tech industries.

Demand-pull: aggregate demand, market growth and population density.

Both: skilled human capital, high-tech labour pools, labour market thickness and foreign born.

For supply-push, we measured the commercialization of new knowledge and knowledge spillovers with patents per capita across the metropolitan areas.Footnote3 We measured research activity as the presence of Research I universities, research funding at these universities, NIH grants received per capita and SBIR grants per capita. The latter three measures of research funding are highly correlated. We test NIH and SBIR grants per capita in separate models because some SBIR funds are disbursed through the NIH.

Localization economies are expected to impact high-tech start-up rates more than overall start-up rates. These external economies should increase with more high-tech firms. We used the LQ of employment in high-tech industries as computed by the Milken Institute to reflect the existing concentration of firms in high-tech sectors. This measure shows the relative concentration of high-tech covering high-tech manufacturing and specialized services in software, telecommunications, computer and architectural design, engineering, and medicine (DeVol, Klowden, Bedroussian, & Yeo, Citation2009). These sectors approximate but do not replicate the sectors included in the high-tech start-up rate measure.

The demand-pull hypothesis primarily depends on the size, growth and density of demand. We measured each metropolitan area’s total personal income to reflect the level of demand from the Woods and Poole Database, recent population growth to pick up market expansion from the American Community Survey (ACS), and population density within 1 mile of city hall (US Census Bureau, Citation2012). The 1-mile density measure better reflects agglomeration than citywide population density, as the political boundaries of cities vary substantially.

We recognized the importance of skilled human capital by including the per cent of adults with college degrees or higher, calculated from the education variable (EDUC) in the ACS. This percentage may be higher in research-oriented metropolitan areas. We measured high-tech labour pools and labour market thickness in the following manner.

Following Chapple, Markusen, Schrock, Yamamoto, and Yu (Citation2004), we defined high-tech labour as workers in Science, Technology, Engineering, and Math (STEM) occupations. The three major categories are 15: Computer and mathematical, 17: Architecture and engineering, and 19: Life, physical and social science. For each occupation group, the labour pool measure we computed accounts for two dimensions: the relative importance of the occupation group within the metropolitan area and its absolute importance as a share of total employment in that occupation for all metropolitan areas. We computed the LQ to indicate the relative importance of the occupation group in each metropolitan area.

To account for the absolute size of the occupation group in each metropolitan area we completed the following tasks. First, we established four size ranges based on the total number of workers in all metropolitan areas in that occupation group. The ranges we set were (1) the average number in the group for all 366 metropolitan areas or fewer; (2) the range from this average to the number of workers representing 0.5% of the US total; (3) the range from 0.5% to 1.0% of the US total; and (4) the range over 1.0% of this total. After some experimentation, we assigned the following values to each of these four ranges: 1.0, 1.25, 1.5 and 2.0. For example, if a metropolitan area had the average number of workers or fewer, its score was 1.0. If a metropolitan area’s share of workers was more than 1% of the total, its score was 2.0. We then multiplied this score by the LQ for that occupation group in each metropolitan area. Finally, we added the weighted LQs for the three occupation groups to compute one overall measure for each area. Although this measure is complex, it is one way to combine relative importance and absolute share of total in one measure. We did not separate and include these two variables because of the high anticipated correlation between the size variable, such as log of employment, and total personal income – our most important demand-pull indicator.

The measure of labour market thickness was less complicated. We measured labour market turnover, which is the reallocation of workers losing and then regaining employment. We assumed that the higher the turnover, the thicker the labour market. We used the indicator of turnover rate defined by the US Census Bureau (Citation2013) found in the Quarterly Workforce Indicator database: the sum of all hires in one quarter plus all separations in the next quarter divided by twice the total employment in the earlier quarter.

For foreign-born, we measured foreign-born adults as a percentage of the adult population, calculated from the birthplace in the ACS. We considered using the percentage of foreign-born adults with a college education as a better indicator of the supply of potential entrepreneurs, but using both college-educated adults and foreign-born college-educated adults in the same models resulted in collinearity. Thus, we used the per cent foreign-born adults in the final models.

We employed two further explanatory variables: (1) the number of adjacent metropolitan areas within 50 km; and (2) the census division in which the metropolitan area is located. Metropolitan areas ideally represent mutually exclusive ‘commuter sheds’. However, census-defined metropolitan areas follow county boundaries. Therefore, some cross-commuting is likely, and its amount may increase as the number of MSAs adjacent to any metropolitan area. We wanted to recognize this influence by counting the number of adjacent MSAs. We used 50 km because we think this distance is reasonable when considering the likelihood of cross-commuting.

Each area is located in one of nine census divisions: Northeast, Mid-Atlantic, East Midwest, West Midwest, South Atlantic, East South Central, West South Central, Mountain or Pacific. West Midwest served as the base case with the other eight regions specified as dummy variables.

Table lists the variables, measures and data sources in this analysis. There are two dependent variables and 13 explanatory variables. We attempted to measure all explanatory and dependent variables as close to 2010 as possible. Excluding the eight dummy variables, we had an array of 14 variables for 366 metropolitan areas, 5124 data points in all.

Table 1. Variables, measures and data sources.

The descriptive statistics for the variables are shown in Table . The dummy variables pertain to eight of nine census regions where the West Midwest region containing 30 MSAs is the base case, as noted above.

Table 2. Descriptive statistics for dependent variables and explanatory variables (n = 366).

Correlations between 11 explanatory variables, excluding the metropolitan proximity and regional dummies, are mostly low, but there are some modestly correlated variables, such as population per square mile and Research I universities (0.74), and patents per capita and high-tech LQ (0.62). High-tech labour pool is correlated with high-tech LQ (0.75), college completion rate (0.63) and patents per capita (0.60). We will closely test the collinearity in the next section.

EMPIRICAL RESULTS

We used two models to test the hypotheses. The four human capital-related variables may be important in either model. We expected the three ‘pure’ demand-pull factors to explain the variation in the start-up rates for businesses in all sectors, but not in high-tech sectors. Conversely, we expected the four ‘pure’ supply-push factors to explain the variation in start-up rates for businesses in high-tech sectors only.

The models can be specified as follows:

where y is either business start-up rates in all sectors or the natural log of high-tech start-up rates; a is the intercept term for each model; b1 to b12 are the coefficients for the 11 explanatory variables and the adjacent metropolitan areas, one set for each model; x1 to x11 are the 11 demand-pull or supply-push factors used in each model; x12 is the adjacent metropolitan area variable in each model; d1 to d8 are the coefficients for the dummy variables entered as 0–1 values depending on location in eight of the nine regions; and e is the error term for each model.

The distribution for start-up rates in all sectors was symmetrical, but the distribution for high-tech start-ups was right skewed. The log transformation for high-tech start-ups made the distribution more symmetrical, allowing us to apply ordinary least squares (OLS) analysis. For each model, we ran the variance inflation factor (VIF) test for collinearity and the Breusch–Pagan/Cook–Weisberg test for heteroskedasticity. The tests indicated that collinearity did not threaten either model. The average VIF for the explanatory variables was 2.86 with individual scores ranging from 1.5 to 5.7. However, both models were heteroskedastic, which is not surprising given some of the variable ranges shown in Table . We calculated robust standard errors to address heteroskedasticity, which increases standard errors and lowers levels of significance. We considered only the 1% and 5% levels of significance, as explained below.

These cross-sectional models cannot generate causal inferences; they can only reveal associations between the dependent and explanatory variables. Yet, it is worth considering whether the start-up rates could influence the explanatory variables (endogeneity). We think this is unlikely for almost all of the explanatory variables.Footnote4 There is a chance that start-up rates around 2010 could influence population growth rates between 2006 and 2010. There is greater likelihood of interaction between start-up rates and labour turnover. For example, employees losing employment may withdraw from the labour market to start firms. Having said this, our objective here is employ a model that indicates correlations, not causality.

With those points in mind, we examined the following:

Adjusted R2 to indicate whether the models explain a reasonable amount of variation in the dependent variables.

The significance of the explanatory variables at the 5% or 1% level.

The direction of association between significant explanatory variables and start-up rates, not specific coefficient values.

The regression results for the two models are presented in Table . The models explain a reasonable amount of variation: 45% for all start-ups and 61% for high-tech start-ups.

Table 3. Regression results for all businesses and high-tech start-ups.

With respect to statistical significance and direction of relationships, we first look at the pure demand-pull variables. All three, total personal income, population growth and density, are highly significant in the model for all start-ups. This result provides strong support for the demand-pull hypothesis. The only caveat is that population density has a negative coefficient probably resulting from its very high correlation with total personal income (0.86). Equally important is the result that total personal income and population growth are also significant in the model for high-tech start-ups.

As hypothesized, the pure supply-push variables – patents, Research I universities, NIH or SBIR funding, and high-tech LQ – are not significant in the model for all business start-ups. However, only high-tech LQ is significant in the high-tech starts model. It makes sense that high-tech start-up rates are higher where high-tech sectors are more prominent. These results provide only modest support for the supply-push hypothesis.

The remaining four human capital variables pertain to both hypotheses with caveats. Two are significant in the all sector model and three in the high-tech one: per cent foreign-born adults and labour turnover associate with starts in all sectors. Our interpretation is that foreign-born adults directly contribute by starting new businesses. Higher labour turnover rates may generate potential entrepreneurs from among displaced workers.

The three human capital factors significant in the model for high-tech start-ups are per cent adults with a college education or higher, high-tech labour pools and, again, labour turnover. The significance of college graduates represents skilled human capital for high-tech start-ups. It is equally straightforward with high-tech labour pools and the availability of more specialized talent. Higher labour turnover rates comport with thicker labour markets that associate also with high-tech start-ups.

Per cent foreign born is not statistically significant for the high-tech start-ups. We interpret this result that the largest foreign-born group is Hispanics. Other immigrants, such as Indians or Chinese, are less prominent. Hispanic immigrants appear more likely to start locally oriented businesses that are not in high-tech sectors.

All significant variables have positive associations with the dependent variables as expected.

Among the regional dummy variables, there are three statistically significant relationships. The dummies for the high-growth South Atlantic region are positive and significant in both models. The dummy for the Mountain region has a positive shift parameter in the high-tech starts model.

Although adjusted R2 is lower, the model for start-up rates in all sectors has five of seven demand-pull related variables significantly associated and none of the four pure supply-push factors associated. Although three of four human capital-related variables are significant in the high-tech start-ups model, only one of four pure supply-push variables is significant, which simply indicates that the higher presence of high-tech sectors is associated with higher high-tech start-up rates. Neither the presence of Research I universities, NIH or SBIR research activity nor patents are associated. All these variables have relatively strong positive correlations with the high-tech LQ, college-educated adults and high-tech labour pools, which are all significant in the high-tech start-up model.

In sum, high-tech start-ups are associated with specialized talent (high-tech labour pools) and skilled labour (college-educated adults) possibly to meet their initial staffing needs. Higher labour turnover would enable rapid hiring to expand or replace workers. High-tech start-ups could also benefit from established high-tech firms that can potentially spawn spinoff opportunities, offer mentorship, become customers or provide other forms of support.

Overall, then, we believe we have very strong support for the demand-pull hypothesis with five of seven variables significant in the all sector model and a different set, but another five of seven variables in the high-tech sector model. We find limited evidence for the supply-push hypothesis as the only significant variable is the high-tech industry concentration. Having no pure supply-push variable significant in the model for all starts provides additional support for the demand-pull hypothesis.

Conclusions

Overall, metropolitan areas with larger, growing, denser markets as well as more foreign-born and higher labour turnover have higher start-up rates in all sectors. For high-tech start-up rates, we find strong correlations with the same factors of larger and growing markets, as well as the high-tech LQ, labour pool, and college-educated population, but no correlation with other supply-push factors: patents, Research I universities, and NIH or SBIR spending.

We believe that our findings may have several policy implications subject to further research. As mentioned above, our cross-sectional analysis does not address causality, but statistical insignificance simply and clearly means no relationship between variables. Given these results, would it not be reasonable to revisit the currently dominant supply-push approach, which, for example, treats research as the raw material stoking entrepreneurial activity? Spending for science parks, university technology transfer offices and federal-government research funding through the NIH, SBIR or the National Nanotechnology Initiative (NNI) is often justified on the grounds of promoting greater economic competitiveness (McCray, Citation2005; Motoyama, Appelbaum, & Parker, Citation2011). Our results point to the need for more definitive research on whether such spending will yield greater overall start-up activity or even high-tech start-up activity. Note that the federal government annually spends roughly US$20 billion for NIH, US$2 billion for SBIR and another US$2 billion for NNI. This spending may achieve important purposes for scientific development, but may not translate into greater economic competitiveness at least as measured by two types of start-up activities. Having said this, it is possible that these research inputs may correlate with start-up rates with time lags, though there is little variation over time about the presence of Research I universities. Future research should address whether and how long those time lags may exist between research-related factors and start-up rates.

In contrast to the presence of Research I or research-active universities, the basic educational role of universities – producing college-educated adults – is statistically related to high-tech start-ups. This echoes some past studies that did not find the roles of universities in start-up rates, but indirectly as the supplier of human capital (Faggian & McCann, Citation2006; Motoyama & Mayer, Citation2017). Further research should test whether all universities, not just Research I universities, are important contributors to entrepreneurship promotion.

We found that high-tech industry concentrations are associated with high-tech start-up rates, which ties back to agglomeration theory operating through localization economies. Further research should investigate the policy of promoting high-tech start-ups where high-tech sectors are present in the region. Initiatives designed to stimulate high-tech start-ups in metropolitan areas without high-tech sectors may not be promising.

Finally, although all start-ups may be acknowledged as entrepreneurship, start-ups that can become major companies serving larger markets (growth entrepreneurship) deserve more nurturing. Their success should eventually increase local demand that should subsequently induce start-ups that serve the local market. Therefore, future research should address which regions appear to foster ‘growth’ entrepreneurship using more sophisticated models to ferret out relationships. Although policy implications must await further research, this study of demand-pull and supply-push factors conducted for all metro areas in the United States is an important first step.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Funding

This project was partially funded by the Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation.

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful for the comments made by three reviewers. They are also thankful for the research assistance provided by Yan Chen and Rachel Atkinson.

Notes

1. This work is a clear departure from the old debate by Birch (Citation1987) and his critics, which focused on the role of ‘small’ companies and only the employment level, not the ‘net’ job creation.

2. The pairwise correlation between the start-up rate for all sectors and high-tech sectors is only 0.41.

3. For limitations of patents as a measure of knowledge spillover, see Griliches (Citation1990) and Audretsch and Feldman (Citation1996).

4. Neither start-up rate is likely to influence patent production, location of Research I universities, university-based research activity, total personal income, population density, college-educated adults, workers in STEM occupations or foreign-born adults. The high-tech LQ was measured in 2007 prior to the start-up rate measures.

References

  • Acs, Z. J., & Armington, C. (2006). Entrepreneurship, geography, and American economic growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511510816
  • Acs, Z., Audretsch, D., & Lehmann, E. E. (2013). The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 41, 757–774.10.1007/s11187-013-9505-9
  • Alañón-Pardo, Á., & Arauzo-Carod, J. (2013). Agglomeration, accessibility and industrial location: Evidence from Spain. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 25, 135–173.10.1080/08985626.2012.710263
  • Anselin, L., Varga, A., & Acs, Z. (1997). Local geographic spillovers between university research and high technology innovations. Journal of Urban Economics, 42, 422–448.10.1006/juec.1997.2032
  • Arauzo-Carod, J., & Manjón-Antolín, M. (2012). (Optimal) spatial aggregation in the determinants of industrial location. Small Business Economics, 39, 645–658.10.1007/s11187-011-9335-6
  • Ashcroft, B., & Love, J. H. (1996). Firm births and employment change in the British counties: 1981-89. Papers in Regional Science, 75, 483–500.10.1007/BF02412291
  • Audretsch, D. B., & Feldman, M. P. (1996). R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. American Economic Review, 86, 630–640.
  • Audretsch, D. B., & Feldman, M. P. (2004). Knowledge spillovers and the geography of innovation. In J. Vernon Henderson & J.-F. Thisse (Eds.), Handbook of urban and regional economics (pp. 2713–2740). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
  • Audretsch, D. B., Hülsbeck, M., & Lehmann, E. E. (2012). Regional competiveness, university spillovers and entrepreneurial activity. Small Business Economics, 39, 587–601.10.1007/s11187-011-9332-9
  • Audretsch, D. B., Link, A. N., & Scott, J. T. (2002). Public/private technology partnerships: Evaluating SBIR-supported research. Research Policy, 31, 145–158.
  • AUTM. (2012). AUTM U.S. Licensing activity survey. Deerfield, IL: Association of University Technology Managers.
  • AUTM. (2016). Principles and guidelines. Retrieved from http://www.autm.net/advocacy-topics/government-issues/principles-and-guidelines/
  • Birch, D. L. (1987). Job creation in America: How our smallest companies put the most people to work. New York, NY: Free Press.
  • Brown, R., & Mason, C. (2017). Looking inside the spiky bits: A critical review and conceptualisation of entrepreneurial ecosystems. Small Business economics, Online First, 1–20
  • Chapple, K., Markusen, A., Schrock, G., Yamamoto, D., & Yu, P. (2004). Gauging metropolitan “High-Tech” and “I-Tech” activity. Economic Development Quarterly, 18, 10–29.10.1177/0891242403257948
  • Chinitz, B. (1961). Contrasts in agglomeration: New York and Pittsburgh. American Economic Review, 51, 279–289.
  • Cooper, R. S. (2003). Purpose and performance of the Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) program. Small Business Economics, 30, 137–151.10.1023/A:1022212015154
  • Deaton, A. (2003). Health, inequality, and economic development. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 113–158.10.1257/jel.41.1.113
  • Degroof, J.-J., & Roberts, E. B. (2004). Overcoming weak entrepreneurial infrastructures for academic spin-off ventures ( Industrial Performance Center Working Paper Series). Cambridge, MA: MIT.
  • DeVol, R. C., Klowden, K., Bedroussian, A., & Yeo, B. (2009). North America’s high-tech economy: The geography of knowledge-based industries. Santa Monica, CA: Milken Institute.
  • Doran, J., McCarthy, N., & O’Connor, M. (2016). Entrepreneurship and employment growth across European regions. Regional Studies, Regional Science, 3, 121–128.10.1080/21681376.2015.1135406
  • Drucker, J. (2011). Regional industrial structure concentration in the United States: Trends and implications. Economic Geography, 87, 421–452.10.1111/ecge.2011.87.issue-4
  • Drucker, J., & Feser, E. (2012). Regional industrial structure and agglomeration economies: An analysis of productivity in three manufacturing industries. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 42, 1–14.10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2011.04.006
  • Duranton, G., & Kerr, W. R. (2015). The logic of agglomeration ( NBER Working Paper 21452). Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research, February.10.3386/w21452
  • Evans, A. W. (1986). Comparisons of agglomeration: Or what Chinitz really said. Urban Studies, 23, 387–389.10.1080/00420988620080561
  • Faggian, A., & McCann, P. (2006). Human capital and regional knowledge assets: A simultaneous equation model. Oxford Economic Papers, 583, 475–500.10.1093/oep/gpl010
  • Fairie, R. (2010). Kauffman index of entrepreneurial activity. Kansas City, MO: Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation.
  • Fairlie, R. (2014). Kauffman index of entrepreneurial activity. Kansas City, MO: Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation.
  • Feldman, M. P., & Florida, R. (1994). The geographic sources of innovation: Technological infrastructure and product innovation in the United States. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 84, 210–229.10.1111/j.1467-8306.1994.tb01735.x
  • Fritsch, M. (2002). Measuring the quality of regional innovation systems: A knowledge production function approach. International Regional Science Review, 25, 86–101.10.1177/016001702762039394
  • Fritsch, M. (2008). How does new business formation affect regional development? Small Business Economics, 30(1), 1–14.
  • Fritsch, M., & Mueller, P. (2008). The effect of new business formation on regional development over time: The case of German. Small Business Economics, 30, 15–29.
  • Glaeser, E. L., Kallal, H. D., Scheinkman, J. A., & Shleifer, A. (1992). Growth in cities. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 1126–1152.10.1086/261856
  • Griliches, Z. (1990). Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 28, 1661–1707.
  • Griliches, Z. (1992). The search for R&D spillovers. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 94, 29–47.10.2307/3440244
  • Haltiwanger, J. (2012). Job creation and firm dynamics in the U.S. Innovation Policy and the Economy, 12, 17–38.10.1086/663154
  • Haltiwanger, J., Jarmin, R. S., & Miranda, J. (2013). Who creates jobs? Small vs. large vs. young. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95, 347–361.10.1162/REST_a_00288
  • Hecker, D. E. (2005). High-technology employment: A NAICS-based update. Monthly Labor Review, July, 57–72.
  • Henderson, J. V. (1986). Efficiency of resource usage and city size. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 47–70.10.1016/0094-1190(86)90030-6
  • Henderson, J. V. (2003). Marshall’s scale economies. Journal of Urban Economics, 53(1), 1–28.10.1016/S0094-1190(02)00505-3
  • Hindle, K. (2010). How community context affects entrepreneurial process: A diagnostic framework. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 22, 599–647.10.1080/08985626.2010.522057
  • Jacobs, J. (1961). The death and life of great American cities. New York, NY: Vintage Books.
  • Jaffe, A. B., Fogarty, M. S., & Banks, B. A. (1998). Evidence from patents and patent citations on the impact of NASA and other federal labs on commercial innovation. Journal of Industrial Economics, XLVI, 183–205.
  • Jaffe, A. B., Trajtenberg, M., & Henderson, R. (1993). Geographic location of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 63, 577–598.10.2307/2118401
  • Jofre-Monseny, J., Marín-López, R., & Viladecans-Marsal, E. (2011). The mechanisms of agglomeration: Evidence from the effect of inter-industry relations on the location of new firms. Journal of Urban Economics, 70, 61–74.10.1016/j.jue.2011.05.002
  • Kask, C., & Sieber, E. (2002). Productivity growth in ‘high-tech’ manufacturing industries. Monthly Labor Review, March, 16–31.
  • Lerner, J. (2000). Government as venture capitalist: The long-run impact of the SBIR program. The Journal of Private Equity, 3, 55–78.10.3905/jpe.2000.319960
  • Losch, A. (1954). Economics of location. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
  • Marshall, A. (1898). Principles of economics (4th ed.). London: Macmillan and Company.
  • Mayer, H. (2007). What is the role of the university in creating a high-technology region? Journal of Urban Technology, 14, 33–58.10.1080/10630730801924225
  • McCann, P. (2007). Sketching out a model of innovation, face-to-face interaction and economic geography. Spatial Economic Analysis, 2, 117–134.10.1080/17421770701346622
  • McCray, W. P. (2005). Will small be beautiful? Making policies for our nanotech future. History and Technology, 21, 177–203.10.1080/07341510500103735
  • Moretti, E. (2012). The new geography of jobs. New York, NY: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.
  • Motoyama, Y. (2015). The state-level analysis of high-growth firms. Journal of Small Business and Entrepreneurship, 27, 213–227.
  • Motoyama, Y., Appelbaum, R. P., & Parker, R. (2011). The national nanotechnology initiative: Federal support for science and technology, or hidden industrial policy? Technology in Society, 33, 109–118.10.1016/j.techsoc.2011.03.010
  • Motoyama, Y., & Mayer, H. (2017). Revisiting the role of university in regional economic development: A triangulation of data. Growth and Change.
  • Norton, R. D. (1992). Agglomeration and competitiveness: From Marshall to Chinitz. Urban Studies, 29, 155–170.10.1080/00420989220080241
  • Plosila, W. H. (2004). State science- and technology-based economic development policy: History, trends and developments, and future directions. Economic Development Quarterly, 18, 113–126.10.1177/0891242404263621
  • Porter, M. E. (1998). The competitive advantage of nations. New York, NY: Free Press.10.1007/978-1-349-14865-3
  • Puga, D. (2010). The magnitude and causes of agglomeration economies. Journal of Regional Science, 50, 203–219.10.1111/jors.2010.50.issue-1
  • Sa, C. M., Geiger, R. L., & Hallacher, P. M. (2008). Universities and state policy formation: Rationalizing a nanotechnology strategy in Pennsylvania. Review of Policy Research, 25, 3–19.10.1111/j.1541-1338.2007.00306.x
  • Saxenian, A. L. (1999). Silicon Valley’s new immigrant entrepreneurs. San Francisco: Public Policy Institute of California.
  • Saxenian, A. (2006). The new argonauts: Regional advantage in a global economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  • Saxenian, A., Motoyama, Y., & Quan, X. (2002). Local and global networks of immigrant professionals in Silicon Valley. San Francisco, CA: Public Policy Institute of California.
  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1926). The theory of economic development: An inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books.
  • Schumpeter, J. (1950). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York, NY: Harper.
  • Sedgley, N., & Elmslie, B. (2004). The geographic concentration of knowledge: Scale, agglomeration, and congestion in innovation across U.S. States. International Regional Science Review, 27, 111–137.10.1177/0160017603262401
  • Simon, C. J., & Nardinelli, C. (2002). “Human capital and the rise of American cities”. 1900–1999. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 32, 59–96.10.1016/S0166-0462(00)00069-7
  • Stephens, H. M., Partridge, M. D., & Faggian, A. (2013). Innovation, entrepreneurship and economic growth in lagging regions. Journal of Regional Science, 53, 778–812.10.1111/jors.2013.53.issue-5
  • US Census Bureau (2013). New measures for accessions, separations, and turnover in the Quarterly Workforce Indicators. In LEHD Program Staff (Ed.), Washington DC: US Census Bureau.
  • US Census Bureau. (2012). Patterns of metropolitan and micropolitan population change: 2000 to 2010. Washington, D.C. Retrieved from https://www.census.gov/prod/cen2010/reports/c2010sr-01.pdf
  • Waldinger, R. D. (1986). Through the eye of the needle: Immigrants and enterprise in New York’s garment trades. New York, NY: New York University Press.
  • Waldinger, R. D., Aldrich, H., & Ward, R. (1990). Ethnic entrepreneurs: Immigrant business in industrial societies. Newbury Park: Sage Publications.