1,953
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Law, Criminology & Criminal Justice

Agency theory, corporate governance and corruption: an integrative literature review approach

ORCID Icon
Article: 2337893 | Received 23 Oct 2023, Accepted 27 Mar 2024, Published online: 18 Apr 2024

Abstract

The aim of this study is to revisit the concept of the separation between ownership and control through reviewing studies on agency theory, governance, and corruption. This study applies integrative literature review as research method where the arguments and counterarguments are derived from existing studies. Relevant literature is identified and read in detail using the selected review strategy. The principal goal of the study is to develop an inventory surrounding the key themes of governance, corruption, and agency theory. None of the existing studies addresses the interrelationships between agency theory, corruption, and corporate governance. This study, thus, fills the gap exploring the theoretical and empirical evidence studying the bibliometric sources. The study finds evidence in support of changing ownership pattern from diffuse to concentrated and argues that the change has caused corruption due to deepening agency crisis. The study also finds that the extant literature focuses on applied areas which calls for further studies on core areas. Incorporating the concept espoused by Berle and Means, this study brings practical implication of agency theory in real life and extends the applicability of the concept.

1. Introduction

The theoretical basis of corporate governance dates back to the work of Berle and Means (Citation1932), who advanced the concept of separating ownership from control in relation to large US organisations. They found that the ownership of capital was highly concentrated in the hands of a few organisations with significant economic power. These companies grew larger, and the original owners found it difficult to maintain majority control through shareholdings as stocks were held by smaller shareholders to a larger extent. This led to the usurpation of shareholder power and control by company managers busy running day-to-day operations. Managers are motivated by their own interests which are more often at odds with that of shareholders and owners. They prioritize reinvesting profits rather than distributing them among owners. In some extreme cases, even they seek their own benefits. Managers have been driven by a self-motivating oligarchy with no accountability to the owners they represent. This position can not only be detrimental to the company but also has negative economic and social consequences (Berle & Means, Citation1932). Since then, corporate governance has received special attention from various divergent group of stakeholders. Research community has taken special attention of different dimensions of governance with divergent contextual backgrounds. Studies vary greatly in terms of the scope of studies stretching from the factors affecting governance thinking to consequences of non-compliances with the governance codes. Drawing from wider perspectives, this study makes a connection of corporate governance with agency theory and corruption to bring renewed attention.

The agency relationship in modern corporate world highlights various scenarios with potential dilemmas. One of the very core considerations of governance studies rests on the study of transaction cost. Coase (Citation1937) argued that transaction cost is reduced if authority is given to one set of party or manager to transact business specific decisions. It is the contractual authority which defines the firm. Transaction cost economics elaborates on the incentives and focuses on internal governance structures that constitute the firm as an internal capital market (Rowlinson et al., Citation2006). Concentrating authority into the hands of a few managers can lead to other costs such as errors or expropriation of firm assets by controlling managers. It may also lead to the expropriation of minority shareholders (Ogabo et al., Citation2021). As a result, principal-agent problems develop a fundamental basis of corporate governance perspective of agency problem. The problem arises when both parties maximize their own utility. It increases the likelihood that the agent and principal do not share the same interests or goals, and so it is logical to assume that the agent may not be acting in the principal’s best interest. This is the foundation on which the governance comes under threat and needs to be guided, monitored, and controlled. Governance eventually plays a mediator role between principal and agent to bring congruence.

Contracts are used to establish good corporate governance and ensure managers do not expropriate or waste funds. It clarifies the role and relationship between the managers and the owners and defines what managers can do with the funds. Ideally, contracts would be complete, but it is not always possible to foresee and anticipate future problems or contingencies. Therefore, managers always have some residual control rights to make executive decision when something outside of the original contract occurs. In addition, it is not always possible or practical for managers to ask or consult shareholders. Because managers are experienced and specialized in their role, it may not be feasible or useful to ask shareholders to make business decisions. Managers therefore end up with further residual control rights. Furthermore, contracts can never be over-interpreted if they ever have to be enforced by courts (Grossman & Hart, Citation1986; Shleifer & Vishny, Citation1997). Governance codes are mostly used as a legitimate form of contract which clearly spells out the duties and responsibilities of stakeholders connecting with governance mechanism. This study, thus, highlights the importance of governance in consolidating the interest of the principal and agent.

Incentives and other mechanisms can be used to monitor managers and limit their deviant activity. Such monitoring would lead to additional costs for clients and agents. It is also possible to enter into contracts (bonding cost) with managers to guarantee that they would not harm the owners, if this is the case the principal owners demand compensation for it. The agency relationship causes positive monitoring and bonding cost almost all cases. Despite the above measures, there will still be some divergence between the agents’ actions and the principals’ interests. The principals’ monetary cost borne due to this divergence is the “residual loss” to the principal’s value or welfare. Thus, Jensen and Meckling (Citation1976) proposed three components of agency costs, namely, monitoring cost, bonding cost to agents and residual loss from decision making which are shown in below. In a study, ElKelish (Citation2018) finds agency costs having a significant negative impact on corporate governance risk across countries. The principal or firm will find a contract that is in balance and weighs cost and benefits. This tie neatly with the transaction cost view of Coase (Citation1937) that firm boundaries are where the marginal cost saving from transacting within the firm equals the rigidity costs in tackling the agency issues and errors made by the agent.

Figure 1. Elements of agency cost (Source: adapted from Jensen & Meckling, Citation1976).

Figure 1. Elements of agency cost (Source: adapted from Jensen & Meckling, Citation1976).

The trade-off between costs and incentives needs to be carefully analysed to check possible governance crisis. Absence of incentives gives entry of corruption in corporate affairs. Analysis of the consequential costs of separation of ownership and control becomes more critical when corruption becomes a recurring event (Wawrosz, Citation2022). It sounds undesirable, but the reality is that the regulatory initiative fails to establish financial discipline, which is reflected in more frequent revisions and corrections to regulations, rules, and policies. Many changes have occurred in the global marketplace since Berle and Means (Citation1932) proposed the separation of ownership and control, which was strongly influenced by the ownership structure of large US corporations at the time and the stock market debacle. In this background, this study aims to develop a bibliometric record covering agency theory, governance and corruption in absence of similar studies. In this study, we find this as a potential research gap and develop an archival record on the revisions that is resulted since Berle and Means introduced the concept. The incremental contribution of this study is to develop an inventory on such relationship based on the findings of various studies done in different context with new research agenda. Based on an integrative literature review, this article develops a renewed research context in line with the following research questions:

  • RQ 1: What is the status of separation between ownership and control?

  • RQ 2: Is there any connection between agency theory, corruption, and governance?

  • RQ 3: How does diffused ownership impact agency problem?

  • RQ 4: What is agency problem and what are the possible remedies?

Existing corporate governance literature focuses on what is known as agency theory. The theory addresses issues in corporate governance, including those related to corruption. The present study also begins with a description of agency theory. However, it expands the scope of agency theory by introducing its application in a broader social context (particularly in real-life situations) and argues that this area requires additional emphasis to initiate new studies to update the literature bring to. Drawing on existing theoretical discourse and available empirical study’s findings, this study develops the epistemological background on which the theoretical foundation of the study rests. The remaining discussion is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses literature review while Section 3 presents the research methodology. Section 4 covers analysis and results. Discussions are presented in Section 5, followed by research limitations and the identification of new research areas in Section 6. Finally, it ends in Section 7.

2. Literature review

Studies on corporate governance are abundance in literature. It began with the concept of the separation of management from owners. The separation between ownership and control (Berle & Means, Citation1932) gets popularity in literature as Agency Theory. The fundamental governance theory underpinning ownership structure is the agency theory (Ogabo et al., Citation2021). It refers to the contractual view of the firm (Coase, Citation1937), where transaction costs exist in the real world. The contract between the principal and manager is very important to ensure a precaution against possible confliction. However, it was previously ignored by the neoclassical literature. An agency relationship arises when the principal (owner) engages the agent (manager) to act on his behalf and also delegates decision-making authority to the agent (Jensen & Meckling, Citation1976). It is a question of trust on part of the principal in terms of the ability and interest of the agent to act for the best interest of the principal. Corruption results from the potential breach of trust, the fiduciary relationship (Johnson, Citation2019).

Separation of ownership and control requires good governance and involves various mechanisms within the institution and in the marketplace to ensure good governance and reduce agency problems (Dockery et al., Citation2012; Farooq et al., Citation2022). A strong mechanism of corporate governance can help bridge the gap between management and shareholders (Sehrawat et al., Citation2019). It can minimize agency costs as investors (particularly institutional investors) like to invest in well-run companies (Mehmood et al., Citation2019). Shleifer and Vishny (Citation1997) also mention different corporate governance mechanisms including legal and economic perspectives. The competitive nature of markets for raising the cheapest debt capital would allow governance without the need for competitive reforms to reduce costs and accept best corporate practices (Alchian, Citation1950; Stigler, Citation1958). However, Shleifer and Vishny (Citation1997) point out that this theory would not address the problems of corporate governance, since competitive markets can reduce the total amount subject to managerial expropriation. But it doesn’t stop managers from seizing companies’ competitive returns. Therefore, corporate governance requires different economic and legal mechanisms and cannot simply be left to competitive market forces (Barros et al., Citation2019).

Research supports the use of incentives to control the behaviour of corporate managers in their possible expropriation attempts. Various incentive contracts (such as share ownership, stock options, and threats of dismissal) can be used to align manager and owner interests (Fama, Citation1980; Jensen & Meckling, Citation1976). Jensen and Meckling (Citation1976) focused on the incentives faced by both the principal and the agent to mitigate potential divergences between them. Fight against corruption is strongly connected with the incentive mechanisms. Thus, the code of governance in different jurisdictions finds resemblances with those of anti-corruption. Corruption is found deeply rooted in countries around the world and these countries suffer from economic development, lack of democracy, and compromising social justice and the rule of law (Al-Faryan & Shil, Citation2023).

Developed countries have studied the consequences of bad governance and the fall of corporate giants as a result of corporate scandals further compel such countries to develop stringent codes of governance. The traditional view of agency relationship based on ownership structure has been reformed resulting reforms in governance requirements across countries. Al-Faryan and Shil (Citation2023) argue that lack of governance leads to the high possibility of corruption in the absence of accountability and transparency. Absence of governance mechanism widens the gap between the owners and managers which develops agency crisis and increases agency costs significantly. This wide dispersion also develops the possibility of corruption in corporate management. Studies consider the connection of corporate governance with firm performance (Guluma, Citation2021), agency cost (Li, Citation2020), Polity (Al-Faryan & Shil, Citation2023), and many other factors. Several empirical studies have documented the costs of separation between ownership and control like self-interest actions involving capital structure (Leland, Citation1998), dividend policy decision (Fenn & Liang, Citation2001), executive remuneration (Hartzell & Starks, Citation2003), mergers and acquisitions (Masulis et al., Citation2009), earnings management (García-Meca & Sánchez-Ballesta, Citation2009), and the issue of shares (Barclay et al., Citation2007). 

On fall of Enron and introduction of SOX 2002, the governance research has witnessed a sudden jerk (Driel, Citation2019). Stringent codes are developed, implementation is monitored and certified, ownership structure is revisited, fraud and expropriation are checked. However, the studies are widely scattered, and wide varieties of issues are covered considering the contextual background of various studies. There is a dearth of studies that connect Governance with agency costs and corruption and thus, this study sheds light on this issue.

3. Research methodology

This study uses the literature review method to answer the research questions. Literature review method is one of the best methodological tools to find answers to a variety of research questions (Snyder, Citation2019). This study develops a solid foundation to advance knowledge of agency theory by confirming findings and perspectives from various published works. To emerge something beyond replication of previous results, a high-quality literature review needs to uncover mysteries on choosing relevant articles to gather data and additional insights (Palmatier et al., Citation2018). Through this method, our special focus is on (a) discussing relevant literature in selected areas, (b) identifying gaps in existing research, and (c) creating new research agendas. To assess, analyse, and synthesize the relevant literature on agency theory, we used integrative reviews to develop new theoretical frameworks and perspectives (Torraco, Citation2016). To overview the existing body of knowledge, most integrative reviews intend to consider mature issues. It aims to critically review and re-conceptualize existing knowledge so that an extension of the theoretical basis of the selected topic can be undertaken for further exploration (Snyder, Citation2019). This study is no exception. Our integrative review follows the below steps ().

Figure 2. Literature review method (Source: Shil & Chowdhury, Citation2024).

Figure 2. Literature review method (Source: Shil & Chowdhury, Citation2024).

We begin with selecting few research questions (we have identified and presented few research questions in introduction section). Integrative review allows either narrow or broadly focussed research questions. After the identification of research questions and the selection of an overall review approach, a search strategy needs to be finalized for identifying relevant literature (Snyder, Citation2019). A search strategy encompasses the selection of search terms and databases and deciding on criteria for inclusion and exclusion. We have identified four search terms, e.g. agency theory, corruption, corporate governance, and remedies of agency problem. We have selected six academic databases, e.g. Elsevier, Emerald, JSTOR, Springer, Wiley, and Taylor & Francis for selecting relevant articles. However, it becomes difficult for us to locate appropriate articles that will help us to proceed with our research questions. Two reviewers have been recruited to help us with the process. We have later chosen the rules for inclusion considering only specific journal with mentioning the time period. It also fails to serve our purpose. We may end up with a very flawed or skewed sample if we limit our selection to some specific journals, years, or even search terms. We may also miss studies that contradict other studies or would have been more relevant to our case (Snyder, Citation2019). It may provide false evidence of a specific effect or even identify wrong gaps in the literature. We have finally selected Google Scholar database and use the selected search terms to identify relevant works for our study.

A pilot test of the review process and protocol is important while conducting the review. The review process needs validation on a smaller sample for possible adjustments, if necessary, before initiating a thorough review. It may even take several adjustments to get the desired results. To ensure the quality and reliability of the search protocol, we utilized the expertise of two reviewers. Since the search results yield many materials, reviewers are advised to read the abstract of each paper before selecting the article for thorough review. Later, the researchers sit down with the reviewers to carry out the review step by step; (a) reading the abstracts first for the initial selection and (b) reading the full-text articles later before the final selection (Snyder, Citation2019). To identify other potentially relevant articles, the researchers also checked the references of selected articles as an additional strategy.

Once final sample is selected, the important phase of literature review begins with the deployment of specific technique to conduct an analysis. An integrative review doesn’t follow any standard for data analysis (Whittemore & Knafl, Citation2005). It may follow descriptive pattern presenting information, such as authors with years published, kind of study, topic, including major findings. It may sometimes present central idea or theoretical perspective considered in the studies to conceptualize for general understanding. The final structure of a review article is based on the selected approach which dictates the kinds of information required and the level of details. While writing the review, we make an integration of historical analysis within a research field (e.g. Carlborg et al., Citation2014), a plan for further research (e.g. McColl-Kennedy et al., Citation2017), a theoretical model or categorization (e.g. Snyder et al., Citation2016; Witell et al., Citation2016), and evidence of an effect (e.g. Verlegh & Steenkamp, Citation1999). We have developed the following conceptual framework () to support us in writing integrative review in next section.

Figure 3. Conceptual framework of the study.

Figure 3. Conceptual framework of the study.

4. Analysis and results

This analysis is the outcome of integrative literature review. Our thematic analysis results few key themes with reference to which we have structured the analysis. The separation between ownership and control resulted agency theory, which has been extensively researched during recent decades. Corruption becomes a big industry driven mostly by agency problems and regulators are looking for solutions that have spawned the concept of corporate governance. In this section, relevant literature is presented in line with research questions and selected themes.

4.1. Separation of ownership and control: synthesizing Berle and Means

In the Modern Corporation and Private Property, Berle and Means (Citation1932, Citation1968) introduced the concept of Agency Theory bringing a separation of ownership and control, which has become an area of debate, criticism, and research. The book comprises an analysis of large US corporations, particularly of the USA’s then 200 largest non-financial companies, most of which, in the early decades of the century, had gross assets of over US$100 million. The book’s thesis is twofold. First, there is a difference between law and practice. The law demands that corporations should behave in such and such a way that does not necessarily imply that they do. In other way, it is to fall prey to the naturalistic fallacy, namely, to derive is from ought (Wormser, Citation1933). The real world of business is different from the paper world of statute. The book’s second point follows from the first. In large corporations, ownership is separate from management. Ownership comprises shareholders, most of whom have little to no direct control of the company. Management is performed by company executives, who may or may not have shares in the company. In any event, the interest of shareholders is different from that of managers. The interest of shareholders is to receive as much return from their investment as possible; the interest of managers is to mulct as much as they can. Managers may mulct their companies by awarding themselves needlessly high pay; by shirking; by awarding themselves undeserved perquisites; or by engaging in such non-profit making activities as empire-building and needlessly increasing sales (see, e.g. Fama, Citation1980). Given that immediate control of the company rests with managers, they have the power to mulct vast amounts from the companies that employ them.

Rather introducing agency theory, Berle and Means (Citation1968) analyse the problem of large corporations. It brings an integrated study covering issues like an empirical analysis of large corporations, an analysis of corporate law and a theoretical analysis of power with reference to the large corporations in the USA. Berle and Means (Citation1968) provide details of the percentage of share ownership of large corporations in the USA. It turns out, for instance, that the 20 largest shareholders of the Pennsylvania Railroad Co., as of 31 December 1929, between them held a mere 2.70% of total shares, and the largest shareholder held only 0.34% of total shares (Berle & Means, Citation1968, p. 79). It confirms that, in modern corporations, ownership is diffuse, not concentrated. Moreover, in the Pennsylvania Railroad Co., not one director or other senior management held a substantial percentage of shares in the company. Not all companies in the early decades of the twentieth century had as diffuse ownership as the Pennsylvania Railroad Co. Nonetheless, the trend was there. Of the 200 companies Berle and Means studied, only 56% had individual ownership of 20% or more of the stock, which was used as a minimum threshold necessary for control of the company. In only 11% of the companies the largest shareholder held majority shares. Nearly half of US large companies were controlled by their managers, not their shareholders (Berle & Means, Citation1968; Mizruchi, Citation2004).

Berle and Means devote a large section of their work (Berle & Means, Citation1968, pp. 196–254) to an analysis of the legal position of managers, the legal powers of corporations, and the resultant position of stockholders. They do not distinguish between board members and other senior managers like others. This is in part because ‘control lies in the hands of the individual or group who have the actual power to select the board of directors (or its majority)’ (Berle & Means, Citation1968, p. 66). Furthermore, control of a corporation even may be dictated by an outside agency, a bank, for instance, as a condition for a loan. In this regard, Corey (Citation1930) notes that J. P. Morgan wielded his considerable power over other companies by means of a complex interplay of … stock ownership, voting trusts, financial pressure, interlocking of financial institutions and industrial corporations by means of interlocking directorates, and the community of control of minority interests (p. 284). Thus, control of a company may be exercised by means other than board membership or stock holdings.

To highlight power asymmetry, Berle and Means (Citation1968) argue that power has been concentrated in distinct bodies throughout history. In early medieval Europe, for example, it was concentrated in the Church; later, it became concentrated in the state, especially after the reformation. Today, it is becoming, or has become, concentrated in corporations. Berle and Means (Citation1968) conclude their work as follow:

The rise of the modern corporation has brought a concentration of economic power which can compete on equal terms with the modern state, economic power versus political power, each strong in its own field. The state seeks in some respects to regulate the corporation, while the corporation, steadily becoming more powerful, makes every effort to avoid such regulation. Where its own interests are concerned, it even attempts to dominate the state…. The law of corporations, accordingly, might well be considered as a potential constitutional law for the new economic state, while business practice is increasingly assuming the aspect of economic statesmanship (p. 313).

Berle and Means were not, of course, the first to link corporate wealth with power. That big business (capitalism) controls society was argued by Marx (1818–1883) in the nineteenth century (Marx, Citation1974). Moreover, it was not only Marx or his followers who saw the link. For example, writing in 1907 of US railroad companies, Lida Baldwin wrote in The Atlantic Monthly:

Mr. Coleman, the author, speaking of the fight, says, “My fight is still going on, and I tryst it will continue till the insolence of these railroad corporations is curbed … [ellipsis added]” One wonders if throughout the thirty-five years since the article was written Mr. Coleman has continued to fight the good fight and is to-day a veteran of the ranks; or did he long ago become discouraged at the difficulty of teaching the railroads that lesson and give it all up? Or, for in thirty-five years much may happen, did he die amid the battle, still fighting? (Citation1907, p. 682)

Indeed, so powerful were the US’s Robber Barons—the Fricks (steel), the Mellons (oil and finance), the J. P. Morgans (banking), the Vanderbilts (shipping and railways), and the like, Galbraith (Citation1977) argues that they were de facto rulers of the USA during the later decades of the nineteenth century. Berle and Means (Citation1968) key argument, therefore, is not that corporations are powerful; it is that, when wielding great power, ownership of them is often diffused, in effect, ownership becomes powerless. In this regard, they argue that capital in the USA became increasingly concentrated during the early decades of the twentieth century, fewer corporations controlled increasingly larger sections of capital; there was a tendency towards oligopoly and duopoly. However, this increasing concentration of capital led to increasing difficulty for corporation owners to control share ownership, hence the diffused ownership. Everybody didn’t see the diffusion of ownership as necessarily bad. Demsetz (Citation1983) reports of Thorstein Veblen, who argued in the 1920s that the diffusion served, in effect, to transfer power from capitalists to engineers leading to greater efficiency. Veblen was a harsh critic of the super-rich, including the USA’s Robber Barons (see, e.g. Galbraith, Citation1967). Against this, Galbraith saw the transfer of power to technocrats leading to unnecessary growth in the private sector. Galbraith was a harsh critic of large corporations, and, for that matter, the super-rich (e.g. Galbraith, Citation1967).

The influence of Berle and Means (Citation1968) has been immense. However, interest in it mostly centred around social scientists, scientists who tended to accept its broad conclusions (Mizruchi, Citation2004). Most social scientists, including those with Marxist views, accepted the work uncritically. Indeed, a major criticism of the work, when such occurred, was that it was Marxist, an interpretation that failed to see the work’s main point (Wormser, Citation1933). By and large, economists tended to view it as an irrelevance (Mizruchi, Citation2004). The neo-classical economists tended to see the market as self-correcting, so it did not matter who (or what) controlled large corporations: the market would ensure optimal efficiency regardless. In the long run, market competition forces corporations to minimise costs and, in doing so, to ensure credible corporate governance necessary for attracting outside funds (e.g. Alchian, Citation1950; Stigler, Citation1958). Such neo-classicist views ignored the growth in number of duopolies and oligopolies as Berle and Means mentioned: neo-classicist economics works only if there exists perfect competition, or something close to it which requires large numbers of buyers and suppliers.

There are number of flaws in Berle and Means (Citation1968) analysis. They used only US data. There was no guarantee that non-US corporations behaved, or would come to behave, in the same manner as US corporations, even if the non-US corporations operated in sophisticated economies. Furthermore, the period of US history studied by Berle and Means was unusual. It marked, on the one hand, the relative decline in power of the Robber Barons and, on the other, the Wall Street Crash of 1929 and the factors that led up to it. It also marked the period leading up to, during, and after World War I (WWI). US government spending (and debt) exploded during WWI, but, under the Harding and Coolidge administrations contracted—a contraction that possibly led to the post-war US boom of the 1920s (Folsom, Citation2008). Thus, even if Berle and Means’s analysis of the US corporations in the first three decades of the twentieth century was entirely sound, it would remain a moot point whether they behave in the same ways today, and it would equally be a moot point whether corporations outside the USA behave in a similar manner. By the late 1990s, advanced economies other than USA have considered this as a serious issue which gradually affects developing countries as well (Yusof, Citation2016). For apparent reasons, empirical research provided only limited support for Berle and Means (Citation1968). On the crucial issue of whether diffused ownership leads to the mulcting of investors, Monsen et al. (Citation1968), for instance, found only a minor tendency for companies with high levels of owner management to be more profitable than those with low levels of owner management and similar results were obtained by Palmer (Citation1973) and, to a lesser extent, by Larner (Citation1970). Kamerschen (Citation1968) also found no such differences.

It appeared that corporations hired and fired managers in ways not easily explained by Berle and Means (Citation1968). In a study of the sacking of chief executives in the US’s 500 largest companies, James and Soref (Citation1981) found no relationship between ownership power and executive sackings. This was odd in that, if managers were usurping power, one would expect that owners had little power over managers to be unable to sack them. Instead, the study found, company profit was the main determinant: when profits were high, managers tended to stay; but when they were low, managers tended to be fired. Such findings are relatively recent. They were made more than three decades after publication of The Modern Corporation and Private Property, and in that period the USA had changed. A notable US development was her series of antitrust laws—the Sherman Act (1890), the Clayton Antitrust Act (1914), the Federal Trade Commission Act (1914), the Robinson-Patman Act (1936), the Celler-Kefauver Act (1950). These laws were made to prevent the creation of monopolies. Regardless of whether such laws were necessary (monopolies, if they exist, do not appear to last long, e.g. Tullock, Citation1997), the laws had bite. In 1911, for example, the Sherman Act was used to break up John D. Rockefeller’s Standard Oil into smaller, and geographically diverse, companies (Standard Oil Company of New Jersey v. United States, 1911). Subsequent Supreme Court rulings further limited corporate autonomy. United States v. Trenton Potteries Co. (1927) determined that price fixing is illegal per se, for instance, and, controversially, Hartford Fire Insurance Co. v. California (1993) determined that non-US companies operating outside the USA could be held liable if they contravened the Sherman Act. Ironically, The Modern Corporation and Private Property had a major influence on antitrust legislation and its enforcement (Orbach & Campbell Rebling, Citation2012).

In the meantime, the USA introduced tougher laws to control unethical business practice. The Securities Exchange Act (1934), for example, prohibits short-term profits made by individuals (e.g. company directors) who own more than 10% of a company’s shares and the same act prohibits fraudulent trading in securities. The act was strengthened by the Insider Trading Sanctions Act (1984) and the Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act (1988). These laws allow for penalties for insider trading being up to three times any profit made from the insider trading. The prohibitions of these acts were mirrored in Supreme Court rulings. Dirks v. SEC (1984), for example, deemed that tippees (those who receive second-hand information) are liable if they suspected that the sources of the information had insider knowledge and United States v. O’Hagan (1997) established that a company’s inside knowledge is corporate property; therefore, inappropriate use of that knowledge for personal gain (e.g. by company employees) is tantamount to stealing company property, that is, to embezzlement.

Accounting standards within the USA also became tougher. The standards date from 1887, which saw the formation of the American Association of Public Accountants, succeeded in 1916 by the Institute of Public Accountants, with a name change in 1917 to the American Institute of Accountants and a further name change, in 1957, to the American Institute of Certified Public Accountants (AICPA) (American Institute of Certified Public Accountants [AICPA], Citation2020). Meantime, 1921 saw the formation of the American Society of Certified Public Accountants, which was merged into the AICPA in 1936, at which time the Institute restricted membership to certified public accountants (AICPA, Citation2020). The AICPA was buttressed in 1984 by the formation of the Governmental Accounting Standards Board [GASB] (2013). Today in the USA, such bodies promote the use of Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP).

Although GASB recommendations are not enforced under US Federal Law, they are enforced under certain state laws (GASB, Citation2013); moreover, GAAP fall under the purview of the US Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), which was set up in 1934, largely because of the Wall Street Crash of 1929, and whose head is appointed by the US President (Securities Exchange Commission [SEC], Citation2013). The SEC does not set standards; rather, it accepts acts on independent advice (e.g. from GASB). However, the Securities Act (1933) requires that investors receive all significant (including financial) information concerning securities offered for public sale. The same act prohibits deceit, misrepresentation, and similar fraud in the sale of securities (SEC, Citation2013). To this, one may add that the SEC has been responsible for certain US laws (SEC, Citation2013). Examples include the Trust Indenture Act (1939), the Investment Company Act (1940), the Investment Advisers Act (1940), and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (2002), this last being set up in response to the Enron scandal (SEC, Citation2013). Following the Enron scandal, for example, Andrew Fastow (Chief Financial Officer—CFO) of the company, following plea bargaining to drop other charges, was convicted of two charges of conspiracy and sentenced to 10 years in jail; Jeffrey Skilling (Chief Executive Officer—CEO) was found guilty of securities and wire fraud and sentenced to 24 years and four months; Kenneth Lay (Chairman and former CEO) was similarly found guilty of securities and wire fraud and faced a sentence of 45 years, but died before sentencing. All told, 17 Enron employees and 6 Merrill Lynch employees (who were deemed complicit in the fraud) were found guilty (McLean & Elkind, Citation2004). In addition, the company’s accountancy firm, Arthur Andersen, was found guilty of obstruction of justice (for shredding documents) (McLean & Elkind, Citation2004), and though the ruling was later overturned (Arthur Andersen LLP v. United States, 2005) by the Supreme Court because of trial irregularities, its reputation was so damaged that the firm was, in effect, put out of business.

The Enron case illustrates another change in the USA since the time of Berle and Means (Citation1968): attitudes had changed, and so had corporate scrutiny, both by public and by private bodies. The Enron scandal was presaged by a suspicious article concerning its stock price in Fortune Magazine (McLean, Citation2001), an article that, in effect, killed the firm (McLean & Elkind, Citation2004), and public opinion, coupled with bad publicity, appears to have killed Arthur Andersen. This contrasts with, for example, the Robber Baron Cornelius Vanderbilt, whose business strategy, as Galbraith (Citation1967) observes, involved stealing from the public (“The public be damned,” he famously said, p. 49), but whose reputation remained intact.

The change in US attitudes to big business was long in the making. This is illustrated by the Johnstown flood disaster of 1889, which was caused by negligent maintenance of a nearby dam. Over 2000 residents of Johnstown, Pennsylvania, died as a result, and the town was, in effect, destroyed (Johnstown Flood Museum, Citation2013). Significantly, the owners of the dam, who included the Robber Barons Frick and Carnegie, were not held legally liable for the disaster (however, both Frick and Carnegie contributed many thousands of dollars to the relief effort, Carnegie committing himself to rebuild the town). The public outrage following the flood was so significant that the US later adopted the UK law, established by Rylands v Fletcher (1868), that held owners of land liable for injuries caused by mismanagement. It is unlikely that the likes of Frick, Carnegie, and Vanderbilt would have survived the glare of scrutiny, public and private, to which companies today are exposed. In the late 1970s, for instance, newspaper articles alleged that residents of Love Canal, Niagara Falls, New York, were harmed by 21,000 tons of toxic waste dumped underground by the Hooker Chemical Company (now Occidental Petroleum Corporation). So great were the concerns over Love Canal that, in 1978, the then US President Jimmy Carter declared Love Canal a state of emergency, and 800 Love Canal residents were relocated to “safe” areas (Wildavsky, Citation1995). The USA’s Environmental Protection Agency then sued the Occidental Petroleum Corporation in 1996 for restitution, and the company settled, out of court, for US$129 million (US Department of Justice, Citation1995). There is no evidence, incidentally, that the toxic waste harmed any Love Canal residents, nor that it constituted a substantial hazard to human health; moreover, if anyone was to “blame” for the alleged disaster, it was the Niagara Falls City School District, who ordered, contrary to the advice of the Hooker Chemical Company, that a school be built over the site of the dumping (Wildavsky, Citation1995).

This does not demonstrate that companies and company executives no longer behave unethically. The Enron and Lehman Brothers scandal, among many other recent cases, suggest that they sometimes do. It demonstrates that companies and company executives are subject to pressures and scrutiny that would have been unthinkable in the early 1900s, the era that most concerned Berle and Means (Citation1968). This illustrates another change. Corporate responsibility today is very different from what it was in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Rightly or wrongly, corporations are forced to provide safe working conditions, are punished by customers if they do not pursue ethical (e.g. environmentally sound) policies, are forced to provide safe products and services, and are encouraged to ensure that all stakeholders receive a fair deal (Chouaibi & Affes, Citation2021). By contrast, for nineteenth century corporations, the only major concern was profit. An upshot of this is that determining what constitutes sensible investment and what constitutes empire building may be becoming increasingly unclear. If, for example, a company’s CEO deems that the company should devote, say, 25% of its advertising budget to its environmental rectitude, one may ask whether the CEO’s policy is aimed to improve the company’s performance or to enhance the CEO’s personal reputation.

There have been other changes since Berle and Means’s work - the growth in power and reliance on technology, the increasing power of media, the increase in government spending in the western world, the corresponding increased power of governmental and quasi-governmental organisations, the growth of multinational corporations, and the associated rise of globalisation. In addition, Berle and Means (Citation1968) do not discuss how government employees mulct taxpayers; neither do they discuss how such employees build empire. In other words, agency problems do not pertain only to private corporations; they also pertain to government which was unaddressed by Berle and Means. Wildavsky (Citation1995), for example, argues the 1972 US ban on the use of the pesticide Dichlorodiphenyltrichloroethane (DDT) was not motivated by the supposed dangers of DDT to wildlife and humans (at the time of the ban, it appeared safe in both respects, and it continues to appear so, see, e.g. Edwards, Citation2004, Lomborg, Citation2001; Wildavsky, Citation1995, moreover, the ban appears to have cost the lives of 10s of millions of black people, see, e.g. Edwards, Citation2004). Instead, it appears to have been motivated by a desire by the USA’s Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) to increase its power and funding (Wildavsky, Citation1995). The state of corporate governance in emerging economies mostly resemble those conducted in developed countries, particularly in the UK and USA. In a study, the author (Yusof, Citation2016) argues that corporate governance research in emerging economies is different due to different institutional, political and other contexts and such study should utilize different theoretical perspectives. This study also supports this thesis.

4.2 Agency theory, corruption and governance

Agency theory () reduces the problems that surface in the firms due to the separation of owners and managers (Panda & Leepsa, Citation2017). The theory begins with the agency problem which derives from contracting someone else to do one’s own work. The theory relies on three dubious assumptions, namely, (a) People are rational; (b) People are motivated by self-interest; and (c) Self-interest involves maximising financial reward. People are not always rational, and people do not work only for money every time, for instance. Indeed, need theory of motivation claims that people are motivated in a hierarchy when they work, not so much for money, but for self-actualisation (Maslow, Citation1968). This caveat suggests that the assumptions behind agency theory are a simplification. Nonetheless, although plausibly resting only on simplifications, agency theory may provide insight into corporate behaviour leading to the following considerations:

Figure 4. Agency theory.

Figure 4. Agency theory.
  1. For complex working relationships, a principal (e.g. a business owner) must determine the work that needs to be done, and an agent must perform it. This is because either the principal is unable to perform the work, or the principal is unwilling to perform it.

  2. This may lead to a conflict of interest between principal and agent. The source of the conflict is twofold, namely:

    • Principals want agents to work for as little as possible, but agents want the principal to pay as much as possible, ideally, they will cheat the principals.

    • Agents and principals will have different views on risk-taking. At times, agents may be more willing to take risks. At others, they will be less willing. The agency theory covers the agency conflict arising from the opposite risk-preferences between the principal and agent (Panda & Leepsa, Citation2017). Mathew et al. (Citation2020) explored the relationship between board governance structure and firm risk. The study confirms a negative relationship between governance and firm risk.

Imagine a corporation that is owned by shareholders (the principals), not one of whom works for the corporation and not one of whom owns more than, say, 10% of the shares. In such a situation, the everyday running of the company will be managed by its senior executives (Chair, CEO, Company Secretary, etc.), the agents. These executives will be tempted to cheat the shareholders by paying themselves more than is necessary, for example. If so, the shareholders will earn less than they would if they had more ethical senior executives working for them. Therefore, it is in the shareholders’ interests to instigate checks on their executives’ powers. An important principle pertaining to moral hazard becomes operative here. Moral hazard, in economics, refers to any situation in which one party in a contract, because of his or her privileged information, may behave in ways disadvantageous to the other party in the contract. For example, say, one party take risks, but the other party bears the costs if things go wrong (e.g. Krugman, Citation2009). Moral hazard is a ubiquitous problem. In insurance, for instance, an individual may take out an insurance policy when he or she know that he or she is a riskier client than the insurance company knows. A jockey, for instance, may take out insurance against broken bones but not tell the insurer that he or she is a jockey (jockeys have high risk of broken bones). In such a situation, the client pays less insurance than would otherwise be demanded. However, corporations are too big to fail. Thus bankers, for instance, may issue risky loans because the bankers know that, if they lose billions of dollars, the government will not risk the financial disaster that would result failure of their bank. Here, ultimately, taxpayers would pay the cost, but bankers would take the risk, and so derive benefits. Indeed, of the 100 or so banking crises in the immediate decades prior to 2000, all were bailed out at taxpayers’ expense (Boyd et al., Citation2000). Related to this was the recent subprime housing crisis in the United States of America. The crisis emerged because of competition between mortgage suppliers, who, in effect, got paid for supplying loans to high-risk clients (see, e.g. Whalen, Citation2008). When large number of the clients failed to meet payments, the losers were the clients, whose property was by then worth less than they had paid for it; the mortgage companies and banks’ investors; and the taxpayers, who paid for the bank bailouts. The winners were the bank employees who granted the loans, at no risk to themselves. In this regard, Simkovic (Citation2013) observes that competitive mortgage secularisation has been tried three times in US history—the 1880s, the 1920s, and the 2000s—and each time it has been a disaster.

Some problems revolving round agency theory and moral hazard are problematic. An example concerns the US aerospace company, Lockheed scandal of the 1970s. The scandal first emerged when Lockheed’s then Vice-President, Carl Kotchian, publicly admitted to the company’s activities in Japan (Mabrey, Citation2007). Lockheed had paid roughly US$22 million in bribes to secure large sales in the country. The bribes included over US$1 million to the then Japanese Prime Minister, Kakuei Tanaka, and over US$2 million to Yoshio Kodama, a known gangster, who warded off Lockheed’s major rivals, Boeing and McDonnell Douglas. Following the scandal, the USA passed the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (1977), which forbids US companies from bribing foreign officials to secure contracts (Badua, Citation2015). Several things are of note in this scandal. First, although the US Congress, in passing the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act, clearly viewed the company’s activities as unethical, others did not. Kotchian argued that he was forced to bribe the Japanese, for, had he not, Lockheed would have lost business and thousands of Lockheed employees would have lost their jobs. Second, at the time of the bribery, Lockheed did nothing illegal under then US law (e.g. Drucker, Citation1981). Why then, should a company be punished despite acting legally? The agency and moral hazard problems appeared to involve only the then Japanese government, who were stealing from Japanese taxpayers, both by accepting bribes and by, possibly, not buying possibly superior aircraft from Lockheed’s rivals. Agency problems may thus arise when there is more than one agent and more than one principal, and, in such instances, not all agents need to be guilty. There was also a political aspect to the affair. Henry Kissinger, then US Secretary of State, allegedly tried to prevent knowledge of the scandal being made public - this on the grounds that such disclosure would damage the USA’s relations with her allies (Mabrey, Citation2007). Regardless of whether one agrees with Kissinger’s alleged actions, there is a general point. To what extent should one permit a minor transgression for the sake of a greater good, or, conversely, to what extent should one punish a minor transgression at the cost of the greater good?

Many economists highlighted this moral quandary in their writings. Ladd and The (Citation1970), for instance, argues that businesses have no ethical obligations; businesses are defined by specific goals, and specific goals carry no ethical implications. Friedman (Citation1970) broadly concurs: the social responsibility of businesses lies only to their shareholders. In such views, only people have ethical duties, and businesses are not people. Drucker (Citation1981) takes a slightly different angle from Ladd and Friedman. There is one rule for private citizens, another for businesses. If you are attacked by a mugger and therefore pay the mugger not to harm you, nobody would blame you, they’d blame only the mugger. In the Lockheed scandal, the innocent victim was Lockheed and the mugger the Japanese government, most notably her Prime Minister (Drucker, Citation1981). Against such considerations, Martin and Schinzinger (Citation2004) point to ethical problems faced by junior employees, especially, as in the case of Lockheed, engineers. If such employees discover what they perceive as unethical behaviour on the part of their company employer, where does their duty lie, to their company or to the world in general?

Drucker (Citation1981), again, raises an important issue regarding whistleblowing. As of 2013, the whistle-blowers are generally protected by law in the United Kingdom (UK) if their disclosures are made in the public interest (UK Government, Citation2013). However, as Drucker argues, whistleblowing can easily turn into informing, and governance and polity based on informing has a poor ethical record. He cites few examples including the governance of Mao Zedong, the Spanish Inquisition, and the terror campaigns of Rome’s Emperor Nero. By implication, a culture in which whistleblowing is endemic, although promoting short-term ethical gains, may lead to what would be a Stalinist state; also, it is open to abuse. Such considerations do neither suggest that all bribing of foreign officials is good, nor all whistleblowing is bad. They do suggest, however, that determining what is ethical and what is unethical in economic and political behaviour is often difficult.

4.3. Empirical studies—critical analysis

4.3.1. Diffusion of ownership

Some studies on diffusion of ownership have reached broader conclusions in line with those of Berle and Means (Citation1968) (e.g. Baumol, Citation1959; Grossman & Hart, Citation1986; Jensen & Meckling, Citation1976). However, recent studies suggest that ownership is less diffused than Berle and Means suggest; indeed, today concentration of ownership, even in the USA, is often substantial (La Porta et al., Citation1999). Holderness and Sheehan (Citation1988), for instance, determined that there are hundreds of publicly traded US corporations with majority shareholders. Thus, the existence of large shareholders in USA is not an exception, rather it becomes the norm. Morck et al. (Citation1988) also confirmed that there is at least some concentration of ownership in the largest US firms. This suggests that the level of US management ownership has risen since Berle and Means (Citation1968) investigation (see e.g. Demsetz, Citation1983; Holderness et al., Citation1999; Shleifer & Vishny, Citation1986).

In addition, La Porta et al. (Citation1999) report that high level of concentration of ownership is prevalent in other countries, most notably Germany, Japan, Italy, seven Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries, and in developing economies. Indeed, concentration of ownership may be especially high in East Asian corporations. Claessens et al. (Citation2000) studied 2980 listed corporations in 9 countries (Hong Kong, South Korea, Malaysia, Japan, Indonesia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, and Taiwan). Results suggested that a single shareholder controlled more than two-thirds of the corporations. The study also detected national differences. In Indonesia, South Korea, Malaysia, and Taiwan, at least four-fifths of companies had managers who belonged to the controlling owner. By contrast, in Japan and the Philippines, less than half the managers so belonged. The study leaves open the question of whether corporations in corrupt countries retain family ownership and control to limit the effects of corruption. Claessens et al. note, for instance, as regards the difference in concentration of ownership between Japan and Indonesia, South Korea, Malaysia, and Taiwan, that Japan had a tradition of professional management before the Meiji restoration (1868), which marked the start of Japan’s industrialisation (Yamamura, Citation1977).

There are two plausible explanations for the difference in conclusions regarding concentration of ownership between those of Berle and Means (Citation1968) and those of more recent researchers. First, as indicated, the early decades of the twentieth century were unusual, and, in any event, Berle and Means studied only US companies; second, Berle and Means might have been so influential, at least in the West, that company owners reacted to their new-found emasculation by ensuring they didn’t lose corporate control. In emerging countries, corporate governance becomes important due to potential change in their domestic economies which results market based economic reform initiatives during 1980s and 1990s (Yusof, Citation2016). The Asian crisis coupled with few others in emerging countries highlight weaknesses in governance system and become a concern for national and international levels (Singh, Citation2003).

4.3.2. Remedies of agency problem

4.3.2.1. Concentrated ownership

There has been an overall increase in concentrated ownership structures and controlling shareholders become the norm for most of the world’s companies (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development [OECD], Citation2019). Especially in Asia, concentrated ownership becomes a central feature due to the rise of emerging market economies (Lim, Citation2021; Tran & Le, Citation2020). A powerful owner or the block-holders or concentrated ownership can improvise the value of the firm through closely monitoring the behaviors of the managers (Burkart et al., Citation1997). Research suggests that, today, owners are active in limiting the rapacity of their managers (e.g. Kang & Shivdasani, Citation1995). While concluding a study on corporate governance, Shleifer and Vishny (Citation1997) favoured concentrated ownership, and this conclusion accords with the results of the studies reviewed above. The high concentration of company ownership may influence the agency conflicts between majority shareholders and minority shareholders (Wulandari & Setiawan, Citation2021). In most Asian countries (other than Japan), ownership concentration is prevalent. Such concentration is more likely in small firms than large firms. As shown in , there are few countries where ownership concentration exceeds 60% in large firms as well. Very interestingly, one sixth of total market capitalization in Philippines and Indonesia left under the control of a single family, the Suhartos and the Ayalas (See Claessens et al., 1998b).

Table 1. Ownership concentration of the ten largest firms.

The presence of large investors should serve as a check on rapacious managers (Berle & Means, Citation1968). Gedajlovic and Shapiro (Citation2002) found that the presence of concentrated ownership is associated with greater productivity in Japan. However, in Nigeria, Dockery et al. (Citation2012) found that large investors conspire to cheat small ones, and that this has a negative effect on productivity. This accords with the suggestion of Shleifer and Vishny (Citation1997). It is plausible that Nigerian experience holds true of other highly corrupt countries. In this regard, Dockery et al. found that foreign direct investment in Nigerian companies serves as a break on corporate corruption and an impetus to productivity. This result supports the view of Moyo (Citation2010), who argues that the poor countries in Africa require, not aid, but, among other things, foreign direct investment. The Satyam fraud in 2009 proves the demonstration of human greed, ambition, and hunger on part of the founders for power and money. This case is different than Enron and operationalize the tunnelling effect in an Asian context (Bhasin, Citation2013).

4.3.2.2. Voting shares

Another method might involve favouring voting shares over non-voting shares (Arslan & Alqatan, Citation2020). Zingales (Citation1994) studied 64 companies listed on the Milan Stock Exchange (MSE). The key variable was ownership type. Ownership of each company comprised voting and non-voting shares. Data came from the years 1987–1990. Results showed that voting shares traded at prices 82% above those of non-voting shares. This was odd given that the non-voting stock provided 1.4 times the yield of voting shares. Thus, investors were willing to pay almost double for control of the companies, but at the additional cost of lower return. This contrasts with the findings of other research, which, Zingales reports, suggests that voting stock normally trades at prices only 10–20% higher than non-voting stock. Zingales attributes this to “the very large value of control in Italy” and the “different levels of protection of minority property rights in that country” (Citation1994, p. 147). In other words, investors in Italian companies want control of the companies they invest in more than do investors in non-Italian companies, and this is because Italy is corrupt. Italy appears second only to Greece as the most corrupt country in Western Europe (Italy 2012 CPI: 4.2; Greece 2012 CPI: 3.6). Levels of corruption in Italy appear to have risen since Zingales’s study, but they appear to have always been high (in 2001, the earliest year for which data are available, Italy’s CPI was 5.5).

The study of Zingales (Citation1994) reports three other things. First, the mean market capitalisation of the companies with the two types of shares listed in the MSE was US$931 million, but that of those with only non-voting shares was only US$661 million. Thus, the companies in which executive power was curtailed by shareholders were worth about 50% more than those in which executive power was not so curtailed. This suggests the possibility that control over executive rapacity works. The companies with a mean market capitalisation of US$931 million were worth so much because, in them, executive power was curtailed. Second, voting shares were not only more expensive than non-voting shares; they were also more popular, with an average take-up of 74% of total shares. This suggests the possibility that, to curtail executive rapacity, voting shares must comprise a large proportion of total stock. Third, Italian experience is different from US experience. In the USA, voting stock is most concentrated in small companies. In Italy, it is not. Companies included in the study included Olivetti, Montedison, and Fiat—that is, many of Italy’s largest companies. This result may be explained by the USA’s being much less corrupt than Italy (USA CPI 2012: 7.3). It might be that the relative lack of corruption in the USA abnegates the need for shareholder control over the executives of large companies. Here also notice the possibility of large national differences in corporate behaviour. Of course, generalising from Zingales’s (Citation1994) study is problematic as he studied only Italian companies listed on the MSE. He admits that the ownership of large companies in Italy is different from elsewhere. Referring to agency theory, his results suggest that senior executives try to defraud stakeholders, and, in turn, stakeholders can take measures to curtail the rapacity of senior executives.

4.3.2.3. Lobbying

Zingales (Citation1994) suggests another method to protect owners from executives. They may lobby or force politicians to make new laws or to enforce old ones. Thereby, they may make it illegal or impracticable for executives to steal from them. Lack of law or its enforcement may make things difficult for owners. Various studies (Barca & Trento, Citation1997; Pagano et al., Citation1998; Shleifer & Vishny, Citation1997) report that Italian corporate governance is so undeveloped that it substantially retards the flow of external capital to firms, that is, Italy lacks the corporate mechanisms to easily obtain capital. The situation appears even worse in Russia. In Russia, not only are external sources of capital virtually absent, but managers also regularly divert assets (i.e. steal) from firms due to the weakness of corporate governance mechanisms (Boycko et al., Citation1995). Russia has a 2012 CPI of 2.8., which places it as being more corrupt than such notoriously corrupt countries as Comoros, Côte d’Ivoire, Guyana, Iran, Kazakhstan, Lebanon, Nicaragua, and Uganda. In this regard, Black et al. (Citation2000) argue that the reason Russia failed to rapidly develop a vibrant expanding economy was that Russia lacked the corporate and legal infrastructure to do so. The country further suffered from punitive taxation, bureaucracy, organised crime, and endemic corruption. At present, Russia has a real GDP growth rate of 3.4%, almost all of this is due to oil and gas production upon which Russia heavily relies. Russia was also hit particularly hard by the global economic crisis of 2007–2008 (Central Intelligence Agency [CIA], Citation2012).

Poor governance may affect otherwise healthy and honest economies (Alina & Till, Citation2019). Japan, for example, appears among the least corrupt countries on Earth. She has a CPI score of 7.4, which places her as broadly the same as the USA and the UK. In addition, she owns a democracy and has good rule of law. In its 2010 assessment, the Polity IV project gave Japan a score of 10 for Democracy (the maximum), 10 for Polity (again, the maximum) and 0 for Autocracy (the minimum). However, these are overall standards, and they ignore differences within Japan’s economy. Hanazaki and Horiuchi (Citation2003) observe that Japanese banks lack transparency; in particular, the financial arrangements as regards non-performing loans are opaque to outsiders. Hanazaki and Horiuchi further observe that there are no trustworthy penalties for poor management within Japanese banks. Moreover, the poor governance of Japan’s banks plausibly contributed to the country’s bubble economy during the period 1986–1991 and her economic difficulties thereafter (see, e.g. Krugman et al., Citation1998).

Japan is not alone in having poor governance in her financial sector. Transparency International (Citation2012a, Citation2012b) reports that corruption is highest in those in the financial sector. Opaqueness coupled with poor governance is a plausible causal factor in the recent US sub-prime housing crisis (see, e.g. Schwarcz, Citation2008). Finally, although Japan appears honest and has good polity, corruption appears in the country not only in the financial sector. Iga and Auerbach (Citation1977) observe that the Japanese are remarkably tolerant of corruption in their politicians. Following the Lockheed scandal of the mid-1970s, for instance, Japan President Kakuei Tanaka was found guilty of receiving bribes; yet he was allowed to keep most of his ill-gotten gains and did not serve a prison sentence. Moreover, he successfully ran for re-election in 1976. Berglöf and Claessens (Citation2004) argue that, although much remains unknown as regards corporate governance in other countries, it appears that enforcement is as important as laws and regulations, at least in developing countries. Here Dockery et al.’s (Citation2012; and see Moyo, Citation2010) finding that Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) helps limit corruption in poor countries is relevant. Moreover, they argue, although legislation may be necessary to control corruption, it may not be sufficient. Particularly in developing economies, effective control may be generated bottom up, with stock exchanges, shareholders, and other parties forcing companies to behave honestly. Italy’s experience with stockholders insisting on voting rights over the control of her largest companies accords with this conclusion.

4.3.2.4. Board composition

Much research has focussed on board composition. Such research has concentrated on such issues as CEO duality, the proportion of non-executive directors on the board, and size of board. However, the research has produced mixed, sometimes even contradictory results. Belkhir (Citation2009) found board size, insider ownership, large shareholders, proportion of outside directors, and board leadership structure as acting synergistically to promote good governance. For a sample of banks listed in 11 countries in the Middle East and North Africa region, Issa et al. (Citation2021) show that there is a significant relationship between board diversity and financial performance in banks. Fernández-Temprano and Tejerina-Gaite (Citation2020) also investigate the effect of board diversity on firm performance. Few studies (Calabrese & Manello, Citation2021; Ullah et al., Citation2019) demonstrate a positive effect of women in board representation on firm performance. Vairavan and Zhang (Citation2020) find neither direct nor indirect effect of board racial diversity on firm performance. However, O’Connor et al. (Citation2006) found that sometimes CEO stock options facilitate fraud, but sometimes they discourage it. Similarly, some studies (e.g. Pathan, Citation2009), identify strong boards as a check on CEO power, particularly as regards risk-taking. Kosnik (Citation1987) has argued that outside directors inhibit greenmail, the repurchase of corporate stock at inflated prices. Hence, Kosnik argues that outside directors are good. However, some results are paradoxical. Cochran et al. (Citation1985), for instance, found that a high proportion of outside directors was associated with higher than usual golden handshakes. The inclusion of more outside and independent directors in the board (Rosenstein & Wyatt, Citation1990; Tran, Citation2021) help in making the alignment of the interest among the owners and managers by diligently watching the actions of the managers. Also, despite the feeling that directors are overpaid, Mace (Citation1977) reports of the Hanes Corporation, whose then CEO and president, Robert Elberson, checked on the workload of his outside directors. To his astonishment, he found that they were hard-working, conscientious, and grossly underpaid.

Again, some studies have found national differences. Aggarwal et al. (Citation2007), for example, found that US firms were better governed than non-US firms in general. The same study found that CEO duality does not affect performance. Meantime, as Rhoades et al. (Citation2000) observe from results of a meta-analysis of the influence of outside directors, many conflicting results in the extant research may simply reflect the different methodologies of different researchers. Some authorities argue that such research is relatively pointless. Dalton et al. (Citation1998), in a meta-analysis of 54 studies of board composition and 31 studies of board leadership structure, found no consistent relationship between company performance and board composition, nor of one between corporate performance and leadership structure. Thus, Dalton et al. conclude, “we are not optimistic that further research in the general areas of board composition/financial performance and board leadership structure/financial performance would be fruitful” (p. 284). However, they add:

We would not, however, suggest that boards of directors do not have an impact on firms’ financial performance. A potentially promising avenue for future research may be the relatively coarse-grained nature of board composition itself…. accounting exclusively for the impact of the full board on firm outcomes may fail to appropriately capture the subtleties of these relationships. (p. 284)

In other words, the personal relationships and characteristics of board members may be more important to corporate performance than the broad characteristics of board composition and leadership (Arslan & Alqatan, Citation2020). Dalton et al. (Citation1998) conclusions accord both with common sense and with less academic research. Thus, Byrne and Melcher (Citation1996a), for instance, writing in Business Week on their own research on good boards and bad boards point to the difference between common opinion and business fact:

They [board members] sit in a corporation’s inner sanctum. They settle into high-backed chairs around burnished mahogany conference tables. And what they say and do is often an enigma to anyone outside those closed doors. They are the directors in the boardroom, a collection of names, egos, and experience that serves as the critical link between a public company’s owners, its shareholders, and management.

That, at least, is the theory. In practice, too many boards have been mere “ornaments on a corporate Christmas tree,” as a landmark study of boards by Harvard business school professor Myles Mace once put it—decorative and decorous baubles, with no real purpose. Little more than a claque of the CEO’s cronies, they would quietly nod and smile at their buddy’s flip charts and rubber-stamp his agenda for the corporation (Paras 1–2).

Things do not seem quite as bad as Byrne and Melcher (Citation1996a) opening comments suggest. As of 1996, the USA had many outstanding companies and associated outstanding boards. Significantly, in many cases, the excellence of the 1996 boards was associated with disastrous management in previous years. Complacency and bad management had afflicted, for instance, IBM, Campbell Soup, and Chrysler in the years prior to 1996. This was evident in IBM, who were outmanoeuvred by Bill Gates when he retained ownership of the software his company (Microsoft) wrote for IBM (Gates, Citation1996; Wallace, Citation1993). At the other end of the scale, according to Byrne and Melcher (Citation1996a), some US companies had appalling boards as of 1996. Such companies included Time Warner, Apple Computer, and Disney. From such considerations, Byrne and Melcher (Citation1996b) identify the characteristics of good boards. Such boards:
  1. Evaluate performance of CEO annually in meetings of independent directors

  2. Link the CEO’s pay to specific performance goals

  3. Review and approve long-range strategy and one-year operating plans

  4. Have a governance committee that regularly assesses the performance of the board and individual directors

  5. Pay retainer fees to directors in company stock

  6. Require each director to own a significant amount of company stock

  7. Have no more than two or three inside directors

  8. Require directors to retire at 70 years of age

  9. Place the entire board up for election every year

  10. Place limits on the number of other boards on which its directors can serve

  11. Ensure that the audit, compensation, and nominating committees are composed entirely of independent directors

  12. Ban directors who directly or indirectly draw consulting, legal, or other fees from the company

  13. Ban interlocking directorships: “I’m on your board, you’re on mine” (para. 1)

Such good boards are predominantly proactive. They monitor performance, they set clear targets, they forbid directors to have conflicting interests, and they fire incompetent directors. Moreover, as Byrne and Melcher (Citation1996a) illustrate, they actively train staff with new skills and promote staff on merit; indeed, such policies formed a major part of the revival of Campbell Soup. Bad boards, by contrast, do virtually nothing. Eventually, shareholders oust them if they can. Byrne and Melcher (Citation1996a, 1996b) arguments accord largely with those of Myles Mace whom they acknowledge. Mace (Citation1965) specifically recommended that company presidents, and boards, should show firm leadership. Any president should display:

  1. Leadership in the tough and laborious process of realistically evaluating existing product lines, markets, trends, and competitive positions in the future.

  2. Leadership in the establishment of corporate objectives. (p. 50)

Similarly, Mace (Citation1977) argues that a board’s responsibilities include ensuring accuracy and honesty in its auditors. In the ordinary course of events, auditors may not detect internal fraud, and may not even see it as their responsibility to do so. Companies with a higher concentration of ownership are less likely to demand extensive auditing. However, the ownership concentration plays a minor role in the positive association between internal corporate governance and audit quality (AlQadasi & Abidin, Citation2018). Guizani and Abdalkrim (Citation2021) reports that companies are more likely to engage high-quality auditors and pay larger audit fees if they have higher active and passive institutional ownership. In a study on the asymmetric impact of institutional ownership on firm performance, Daryaei and Fattahi (Citation2020) report that performance increases with institutional ownership. Mace (Citation1972) also observes that a retiring CEO often stays in power to the detriment of the company and the new CEO. Mace (Citation1972) recommends that outside directors should have a stake in the company and should be used to scrutinise corporate policy. Mace’s suggestions also accord broadly with agency theory. Fama (Citation1980) and Fama and Jensen (Citation1983), for instance, argue that owners must monitor managers if the owners are to avoid being mulcted.

4.3.2.5. Executive pay

The evidence on executive pay is mixed. Coughlan and Schmidt (Citation1985) found a positive correlation between executive pay and corporate performance like Murphy (Citation1985) and Benston (Citation1985). Expropriation by managers deepened the financial troubles of the Bangkok Bank of Commerce which becomes a well-documented example in this area (Johnson et al., Citation2000). The owners can maximize their wealth by motivating managers to work harder for the better performance through a periodic compensation revision and proper incentive package (Core et al., Citation1999). Such results led Shleifer and Vishny (Citation1997) to conclude that one can reject an extreme interpretation of Berle and Means (Citation1968), namely that owners are impotent in the face of rapacious managers. However, other evidence suggests the converse. In studies of US, Japanese, and German corporations, Kaplan (Citation1994a, Citation1994b) found that executive sensitivity to pay and dismissal was broadly the same in all three countries, yet the US executives were paid more than their Japanese and German counterparts, a finding that suggests that US executives milk their employers more than they deserve. Against this, Jensen and Murphy (Citation1990) found that CEO pay, in the USA at least, changes (up or down) by US$3.25 per US$1000 change in share value. Jensen and Murphy note here that, although CEO stock ownership provides a powerful incentive relative to salary, most CEOs hold trivial amounts of stock and, in any event, the amount of stock they hold fell in the period 1940–1990. This last observation is consistent with Berle and Means (Citation1968) analysis. Shleifer and Vishny (Citation1997) also argue that high executive pay may negate risk sensitivity among executives while high pay would also provide opportunity for embezzlement. Shleifer and Vishny (Citation1997) further point out that there is little agreement on whether large corporations are managed in a broadly honest or dishonest manner.

Discussion on executive pay often address only the amount of pay, not the type of pay. There are two main types of pay for company employees: individual performance-related and salary. Salaried pay may be augmented by overall company performance in the form of bonuses. Performance-related pay makes a difference for employees less exalted than board members. In a study using Australian data, Drago and Garvey (Citation1998) found that performance-related pay was a strong motivator of individual employees. However, it also served as disincentive to cooperative behaviour among employees. Bonuses, by contrast, seemed to make little difference except when work was both challenging and varied. In such circumstances, bonuses improved levels of cooperation. This suggests that, in cases where cooperation is paramount, performance-related pay hinders performance. By acting selfishly, employees (including board members) may mulct their employers. This suggestion is supported by Alchian and Demsetz (Citation1972) who found strong negative effects of performance-related pay in jobs that require much team effort. Thus, the optimum type of incentive may depend on the type of work being performed.

Against this, Fernie and Metcalf (Citation1999) found that jockeys performed the best when they received a share of the winnings and argue that similar may pertain in other professions including corporate executives. This argument may explain Jensen and Murphy (Citation1990; and see Main et al., Citation1996) finding that level of pay does not affect CEO performance that much, it might be, not the level of pay but the manner of payment. Fernie and Metcalf’s argument also accords with Byrne and Melcher (Citation1996a, 1996b) view that senior executive pay should be performance related. Further, although early research such as that of Jensen and Murphy suggested a weak association between level of senior executive pay and performance, more recent work suggests the relationship is much stronger, particularly when one considers the level of senior executive stockholdings (Hall & Liebman, Citation1998). In this regard, Fernie and Metcalf observe:

Most previous literature on this issue [CEO pay] has examined pay and performance of chief executive officers (CEOs). But generally, such studies do not test agency theory, they do not analyse how agents respond to different incentives. Rather, they simply calculate the strength of links between pay and performance, typically concluding until very recently that the relationship is very weak. (p. 386; emphasis original)

This does not necessarily suggest that company owners’ best option is to reward CEOs and other senior managers with shares. Recent work by Ndofor et al. (Citation2015) suggests that increasing CEO stock options increases the likelihood of fraud, especially in highly complex industries; moreover, the same research suggests that aggressive auditing may not rectify the problem, for it may merely reduce the likelihood of reporting fraud.

Based on the empirical studies conducted in different parts of the world covering developed and emerging economies, we may summarize our discussion on remedies to agency problem in above. The factors may be utilized by regulators keeping the local context into consideration while developing codes and guidelines for ensuring corporate governance.

Table 2. Remedies to agency problem.

5. Discussions

The separation of ownership and control plays a key role in the agency theory and the use of agency cost to manage the agency problem caused by divergence of interest (Fama & Jensen, Citation1983; Jensen & Meckling, Citation1976). Berle and Means (Citation1968) did not introduce the term agency theory, rather, they introduced the concept of separation. Their thinking foreshadowed much of the elements of the theory. Agency theory addresses the problems that arise when two or more parties’ contract to produce a product or service in which one or more parties provide the work, at little personal risk, but one or more parties provide the investment, at considerable personal risk. This divergent risk-return profiles among the related parties trigger conflict of interest which is captured by agency problem. The assumption of the agency theory that there is separation between ownership and control is not necessarily valid globally as not all countries have the diffusion of ownership (Dalton et al., Citation2007). Based on a study in South African-listed companies, Steyn and Stainbank (Citation2013) show that the separation of ownership and control exists, but shareholding is not yet widely diffused. Claessens et al. (Citation2000) examined the separation of ownership and control for 2980 corporations in nine East Asian countries. The separation is most pronounced among family-controlled firms and small firms. The study also reports that significant corporate wealth in East Asia is concentrated among a few families. Chowdhury (Citation2004), like many other researchers, has identified several reasons behind the agency problem, namely, separation of the ownership from control (Berle & Means, Citation1932; Nguyen et al., Citation2020), differences in risk-sharing attitudes between the principal and managers (Grossman & Hart, Citation1983), short period involvement of the agents in the organization, unsatisfactory incentive plans for the agents (Panda & Leepsa, Citation2017; Ross, Citation1973) and the prevalence of information asymmetry (Jensen & Meckling, Citation1976; Panda & Leepsa, Citation2017) within the firm. Most of the studies empirically find the presence of these factors in developed countries including US and UK.

Studying the ownership pattern of the largest corporations in the USA, Berle and Means (Citation1968) found that ownership was largely diffused during that time. In many cases, no single shareholder had control of the company, or anything like it. Thus, Berle and Means argued that corporate power had shifted, and was continuing to shift, from company owners to company employees, mainly the senior company executives. In such situations, there is the potential for moral hazard, those who perform the work may steal from those who pay them. Recent empirical research shows that many publicly traded firms in Western Europe, South and East Asia, Middle East, Latin America, and Africa have large shareholders in control and most of them are often families (Claessens et al., Citation2000; La Porta et al., Citation1999). Johnson et al. (Citation2000, in a separate study on Korean companies found that they are more likely to be subject to various agency problems resulting in lower firm values and they argued that managers are more likely to expropriate minority shareholders during a crisis as the expected return on investment falls. Also, the relation between ownership and corporate control of Korean companies, as La Porta et al. (Citation1999) noted, large shareholders who are also managers are able to use pyramid and cross-shareholding mechanisms to tunnel.

Berle and Means (Citation1968) were highly influential, though their findings were initially ignored by mainstream economists. The neo-classicist economists assumed that any corporate malpractice would self-correct (here, they ignored the increasing rise of oligopolies documented by Berle and Means). Despite admonitions dating from at least the 1930s to the effect that company owners should hold their senior managers in check, corporate fraud seems to continue unabated (Yu et al., Citation2015). This does not only involve such celebrated cases as Enron and Lehman Brothers; it also appears to involve typical US corporation behaviour—behaviour that involves employees cheating employers. This can be seen in David Gordon’s (Citation1996) description of the downsizing of US companies. US companies should become leaner and meaner. Downsizing became popular in the 1980s and continued in the wake of the global economic crisis and amid recession-era. In 2009, Standard & Poor’s (S&P) top 500 companies laid off a total of 697,448 workers, of whom some 531,363 were laid off by the top 50 (Alazraki, Citation2010). The theory behind it was that, if companies eliminated inefficiencies and surplus resources, they would become more competitive. This was important, not only to the companies themselves, but also to the US economy, for the country was then experiencing stiff competition from, for example, Japan. Particularly in the aftermath of takeovers, corporations usually laid off workers do bring downsizing in practice.

Downsizing not only increases number of executives but also increases their pay. Although US CEO pay fell slightly in the years 2008 and 2009, hardly surprising given than these were the years following economic crisis, US CEO inflation-adjusted pay doubled in each of the decades in the period 1980–2000 (it was eight times higher in 2009 than it had been in 1989) (Anderson et al., Citation2010). There are several possible explanations for the rise in CEO pay and the relative increase in the number of corporate managers. The world economy had adjusted such that more managers were needed; may be companies needed to pay CEOs more to attract the best talent; may be the CEOs deserved their higher pay because they had earned it; and so on (Kong et al., Citation2022). However, the most parsimonious explanation is that the CEOs were mulcting their employers. In this regard, Wesley and Ndofor (Citation2013) argue that, in the USA at least, bodies such as the SEC is relatively powerless in detecting executive fraud, and, even if it finds it, may confuse it with accounting error. In contrast, non-managerial workers’ wages fell by approximately US$1 per hour (1994 adjusted) in the period 1980–1992 (Gordon, Citation1996); and by 1994 had fallen, in real terms, to 1967 levels. Empirical tests have corroborated Gordon’s conclusions: in affluent democracies, for example, earnings inequality is positively correlated with managerial intensity, with earnings inequality and managerial intensity being higher in the USA than in European democracies (Leicht & Brady, Citation2012). Empirical studies of agency theory produce no clear conclusions in support of this. It is not clear whether CEO duality helps or hinders firms (Hsu et al., Citation2021). It is neither clear that board size affects performance; nor that level of executive pay keeps executives in check. Moreover, what holds true of one industry need not hold true of another, and there may be national differences (Al-Faryan, Citation2020; Al-Faryan & Dockery, Citation2017).

Most Asian firms are either inherently family-controlled or state-controlled making their ownership traditionally concentrated since their establishment (Shakir, Citation2008). Unlike other emerging Asian economies, concentration of ownership is much more prominent in manufacturing sectors in India (Altaf, Citation2016; Selarka, Citation2005). Pandey and Sahu (Citation2021) have tested this idea on a sample of 91 Indian manufacturing firms using panel data regression analysis for the period from 2011 to 2018. However, the study does not find any evidence of a significant association between ownership concentration and owners–managers conflicts of interest in the sample firms.

Unfortunately, much of the research on agency theory has concentrated on CEO pay. It has not concentrated on the emoluments of other board members, much less on those of other senior managers. Yusuf et al. (Citation2018) find that remuneration packages and board independence are not effective tools for governing owner managers in Pakistan. What appears true of CEOs may plausibly be generalised to other executives, particularly given Gordon’s (Citation1996) findings. The emerging issue is that senior executives pay themselves more than is warranted and manage their companies in sub-optimal ways. Conflict of interest between managers and shareholders leads to so-called agency problem. There are different ways by which shareholders can control the operations of management. Some of the measures that can be used to resolve and prevent this problem are internal audit ((Jovanova, Citation2014), financial rewards (Westerfield & Jaffe, Citation2008), concentrated ownership (Eun et al., Citation2004), good governance system (Larcker & Tayan, Citation2011), effective external control (Larcker & Tayan, Citation2011) etc. Using data for the period 2006–2009, Munisi et al. (Citation2014) examined the relationship between board structure and ownership structure for firms listed on the stock exchanges of twelve Sub-Saharan African countries. The study emphasized that board and ownership structure are both corporate governance mechanisms that are used as substitutes to one another in reducing agency problems. Nonetheless, the overall picture suggests that agency theory is correct. Senior executives tend to take advantage of their position, and in doing so, cheat their employers. Moreover, it is difficult for employers to curtail such executive misbehaviour. This is even more so given that much mismanagement is legal. The use of outside directors, regular auditing, setting of clear targets, and other such measures may ameliorate agency problems, but are unlikely to eliminate them. This conclusion warrants more rigorous studies. Thus, in addition to presenting extant literature on agency theory, corruption and corporate governance, this study presents further areas for exploration based on synthesizing the findings of existing literature.

6. Limitations and scope for further research

Agency theory is driven by the concept of separation between ownership and control advocated by Berle and Means based on which a corporate governance framework has been developed and practiced throughout the world. Widespread financial manipulation and corruption question the efficacy of age-old governance mechanism. Studies found slight evidence to support Berle and Means’s study and identified various shortcomings to the concept. Firstly, the concept was confined to US companies. Secondly, it was referred to an unusual period of US economic history. Thirdly, it fails to consider the vast changes in the US economic environment, including increased anti-trust laws and increased public hostility to corporate malfeasance. Finally, it was limited to private, not government, power, and its abuse. Still, it is unfair to blame Berle and Means (Citation1968) for these shortcomings as they had access only to US data, and they could not, writing in the 1930s, see what life would be like in the 2000s. Throughout these years, the corporate management has witnessed changes due to the dynamism in the filed proving the old mechanism ineffective. Understanding the weaknesses of the thesis of Berle and Means as a potential research gap, this study sheds light on developments to date in areas such as ownership patterns, agency theory, corruption, governance, and solutions to agency problems. It applies an integrative literature review intentionally to develop an inventory based on existing research. New research approach may provide a fresh outlook on the area bringing specific attention based on the chosen context.

Following the financial crisis in different countries in Asia, Russia, and Latin America; corporate governance has become as a major policy issue for many developing countries (Wu, Citation2005). Eisenhardt (Citation1989) emphasized that an appropriate system of governance can reduce agency conflict. He recommended two suggestions to minimize the agency problem. The first is an outcome-based contract, where agents’ actions can be audited. Second, the principal must form a strong information structure in which the principal knows all the information about the agent’s actions and cannot misrepresent the principal. Eisenhardt argues that researchers have paid undue attention to different application areas, creating a major vacuum in core areas. A results-based contract can effectively help to create discipline in downsizing, board compensation, job rotation, etc. An ombudsman scheme can support independent observation on behalf of principals due to failures of the internal control system, in particular the corporate governance framework opens different avenues for internal auditors, independent directors, to do the work that has failed. These findings and prescriptions help regulators to redress policy guidelines whereby different codes and standards are prepared. Empirical results indicate that internal audit professionalization affects internal audit effectiveness and contributes to improved corporate governance for organizations (Alqudah et al., Citation2023; Vadasi et al., Citation2019). Instead of relying on assessment activities, we should focus on preventive measures. The study finds that we let people do what shouldn’t be done and then look for a solution. Rather than looking for after-the-fact solutions, new research should address the development of innovative mechanisms that make the system work perfectly.

The supremacy between Director Primacy Model and Shareholder Primacy Model needs to be tested to evaluate the existing governance structure. The Shareholder Primacy Model is based on contractual theory, where shareholders enjoy control as the principals of contract. In Director Primacy Model, on the other hand, the firm is viewed as a team (Blair & Stout, Citation1999) with shareholders and other non-shareholder groups (e.g. employees, creditors, managers, local government, etc.) as team members. A corporation is a separate legal entity and cannot be owned by its shareholders. Here, enterprise is defined as a complex productive activity involving multiple parties and the outcome of which is neither separable nor individually identifiable (Lan & Heracleous, Citation2010). Shareholders in modern companies are owners of ‘fictitious’ capital that differs greatly from ‘real’ capital (Sikka & Stittle, Citation2019). They are unable to control or direct companies for the benefit of other stakeholders and society in general. Sikka and Stittle (Citation2019) call for the departure from the shareholder model and the empowerment of stakeholders with a long-term interest in the well-being of companies. Based on this conclusion, this study supports a departure from the traditional concept of Berle and Means and urges for new research in different countries, cultures, and economies to articulate empirical evidence. If Director Primacy outweighs Shareholder Primacy, Berle and Means’s thesis will receive renewed attention and the existing corporate governance framework will need a serious overhaul to reduce corruption and ensure financial discipline.

7. Conclusion

What is now known as agency theory has its origins in Berle and Means’s The Modern Corporation and Private Property. The book argues that ownership of modern corporations is diffuse and, as a result, executives run companies at the expense of company owners. Although incorrect in its specifics, the book’s thesis appears broadly correct: company executives have the means and motives to defraud company owners, and often do so. Moreover, although Berle and Means addressed only private corporations, in a similar manner, public servants defraud taxpayers. Such theft, public or private, is often legal.

This study has identified few research questions to bring a renewed focus to the research based on agency theory and applied integrative literature review method to search for the answers to the research questions. It develops a search protocol and review strategy which gather all the relevant studies to synthesize the idea. It discusses the separation of ownership and control determined by stock ownership patterns, e.g. diffuse or concentrated. Criticising the diffuse ownership advocated by Berle and Means (Citation1932, Citation1968), the growth of concentrated ownership is discussed, which offers the opportunity of corruption creating moral hazard (Krugman, Citation2009) among managers. Traditional agency theory has already been debunked with the introduction of Director Primacy Model (Lan & Heracleous, Citation2010; Sikka & Stittle, Citation2019), which needs to be explored further to make policy recommendations on the corporate governance framework. Agency cost arises from agency problem (Nguyen et al., Citation2020) and corruption attempts become severe in absence of governance (Donadelli et al., Citation2014). This study argues that agency problem arises due to various contextual issues (Jin et al., Citation2022) in addition to separation between principals and agents (Arsalan & Alqatan, Citation2020) and identifies various measures to check the problem in addition to governance mechanism (Panda & Leepsa, Citation2017).

Based on existing empirical evidence, this study argues that ownership patterns, agency scenarios, solutions to agency problems, corruption intensity, and governance frameworks depend on various contextual parameters (country, market, legal and political position). Unfortunately, most of the work on agency theory is based on US or UK experience, and such evidence as exists suggests that companies differ according to the nation in which they operate (see, e.g. Al-Faryan & Dockery, Citation2017). However, although nation states differ in their level of corruption, evidence suggests that owners take measures to limit the rapacity of their employees (Arslan & Alqatan, Citation2020). Key among these measures is to ensure that the owners can monitor executive behaviour and can hire and fire them.

Based on existing studies, this study confirms the presence of agency problems and identified few remedies to neutralize the problem, say, concentrated ownership, voting shares, lobbying, board composition, and executive pay (Panda & Leepsa, Citation2017). To develop an interconnection among governance, corruption and agency problems (Donadelli et al., Citation2014), this study reviews existing literature extensively and highlights studies with all possible outcomes whereby the researchers will be benefited greatly. The major limitation of the study is that it fails to apply any empirical research method which remains outside the scope of the current research. Similarly, it limits the scope of the work within few key areas like governance, corruption, and agency issues. This study also calls for in-depth quantitative and qualitative studies covering the governance issues in emerging and developing countries as these countries lack similar studies (Arsalan & Alqatan, Citation2020).

Real life examples were also captured to broaden the notion of related literature. This study trusts that it is important to innovate preventive measures not to maintain the ownership stake, but to free the society from financial manipulation and mismanagement, thereby ensuring efficient use of the world’s scarce resources. Most antitrust laws are passed after someone orchestrated the innovative nature of corruption within the regulatory framework of the time. We have regulatory requirements for, say, internal audit, internal control, market watchdogs (SEC, SOX), but there is still very little sign of improvement. This study prompts researchers to take a fresh look to develop a comprehensive solution.

Acknowledgments

We thank the editor and the reviewers for the helpful comments and suggestions that significantly enhanced this work. The usual disclaimer applies.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Data availability statement

In this study, no new data were created or analyzed. Data sharing is not applicable to this article.

Additional information

Notes on contributors

Mamdouh Abdulaziz Saleh Al-Faryan

Mamdouh Abdulaziz Saleh Al-Faryan is a Board Member and Head of the Scientific Committee at The Saudi Economic Association. Mamdouh is a member of more than forty national and international professional associations. He has worked tirelessly to expand his experience and financial acumen, which would guide him down the path into leadership and higher levels of responsibility. So far, he has several publications in the fields of economics, finance, corporate governance, and accounting, which have been published in top international journals. Mamdouh also serves as a reviewer for a number of international journals and holds academic and research distinctions.

References

  • Aggarwal, R., Erel, I., Stulz, R. M., & Williamson, R. (2007). Do U.S. firms have the best corporate governance? A cross-country examination of the relation between corporate governance and shareholder wealth. Working Paper 12819. The National Bureau of Economic Research.
  • American Institute of Certified Public Accountants (AICPA). (2020). History of the AICPA. http://www.aicpa.org/about/missionandhistory/pages/history%20of%20the%20aicpa.aspx
  • Alazraki, M. (2010). Paid off for layoffs: CEOs at pink slip leaders earned 42% more in 2009. Investor Center. https://www.aol.com/2010/09/01/paid-off-for-layoffs-ceos-at-pink-slip-leaders-earned-42-more/
  • Alchian, A. A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(3), 1–29. https://doi.org/10.1086/256940
  • Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. The American Economic Review, 62(5), 777–795.
  • Alina, M.-P., & Till, H. (2019). Corruption and development: A reappraisal. In Oxford research encyclopedia of economics and finance. Oxford University Press.
  • Al-Faryan, M. A. S., & Shil, N. C. (2023). Governance as an interplay between corruption and polity: Conceptualizing from a national perspective. Economies, 11(2), 65. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11020065
  • Al-Faryan, M. A. S. (2020). Corporate governance in Saudi Arabia: An overview of its evolution and recent trends. Risk Governance and Control: Financial Markets and Institutions, 10(1), 23–36. https://doi.org/10.22495/rgcv10i1p2
  • Al-Faryan, M. A. S., & Dockery, E. (2017). Ownership structure and corporate governance: What does the data reveal about Saudi listed firms? Corporate Ownership and Control, 14(4), 413–424. https://doi.org/10.22495/cocv14i4c2art7
  • AlQadasi, A., & Abidin, S. (2018). The effectiveness of internal corporate governance and audit quality: The role of ownership concentration – Malaysian evidence. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 18(2), 233–253. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-02-2017-0043
  • Alqudah, H., Amran, N. A., Hassan, H., Lutfi, A., Alessa, N., Alrawad, M., & Almaiah, M. A. (2023). Examining the critical factors of internal audit effectiveness from internal auditors’ perspective: Moderating role of extrinsic rewards. Heliyon, 9(10), e20497. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2023.e20497
  • Altaf, N. (2016). Economic value added or earnings: What explains market value in Indian firms? Future Business Journal, 2(2), 152–166. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fbj.2016.11.001
  • Anderson, S., Collins, C., Pizzigati, S., & Shih, K. (2010). Executive excess 2010: CEO pay and the Great Recession. Institute for Policy Studies.
  • Arslan, M., & Alqatan, A. (2020). Role of institutions in shaping corporate governance system: evidence from emerging economy. Heliyon, 6(3), e03520. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2020.e03520
  • Badua, F. (2015). Laying down the law on Lockheed: How an aviation and defence giant inspired the promulgation of the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act 1977? Accounting Historians Journal, 42(1), 105–126. https://doi.org/10.2308/0148-4184.42.1.105
  • Baldwin, L. F. (1907). Unbound old Atlantics. The Atlantic Monthly, 679–684.
  • Barca, F., & Trento, S. (1997). State ownership and the evolution of Italian corporate governance. Industrial and Corporate Change, 6(3), 533–559. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/6.3.533
  • Barclay, M., Holderness, C., & Sheehan, D. (2007). Private placements and managerial entrenchment. Journal of Corporate Finance, 13(4), 461–484. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2007.04.009
  • Barros, A. N. F., Rodrigues, R. N., & Panhoca, L. (2019). Information on the fight against corruption and corporate governance practices: Evidence of organized hypocrisy. International Journal of Disclosure and Governance, 16(2–3), 145–160. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41310-019-00060-2
  • Baumol, W. (1959). Business behavior, value and growth. MacMillan.
  • Belkhir, M. (2009). Board structure, ownership structure and firm performance: Evidence from banking. Applied Financial Economics, 19(19), 1581–1593. https://doi.org/10.1080/09603100902967561
  • Benston, G. J. (1985). The self-serving management hypothesis: Some evidence. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7(1–3), 67–84. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(85)90028-X
  • Berglöf, E., & Claessens, S. (2004). Corporate governance and enforcement. Working Paper No. 3409, World Bank Policy Research. World Bank.
  • Berle, A. A., & Means, G. C. (1932). The modern corporation and private property. Macmillan.
  • Berle, A. A., & Means, G. C. (1968). The modern corporation and private property. Harcourt, Brace & World, Inc.
  • Bhasin, M. L. (2013). Corporate accounting fraud: A case study Of Satyam Computers Limited. Open Journal of Accounting, 2(2), 26–38.
  • Black, B., Kraakman, R., & Tarassova, A. (2000). Russian privatization and corporate governance: What went wrong? Stanford Law Review, 52(6), 1731–1808. https://doi.org/10.2307/1229501
  • Blair, M., & Stout, L. (1999). A team production theory of corporate law. Virginia Law Review, 85(2), 247–328. https://doi.org/10.2307/1073662
  • Boycko, M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1995). Privatizing Russia. Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press.
  • Boyd, J. H., Gomis, P., Kwak, S., & Smith, B. D. (2000). A user’s guide to banking crises. World Bank.
  • Burkart, M., Gromb, D., & Panunzi, F. (1997). Large shareholders, monitoring, and the value of the firm. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(3), 693–728. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555325
  • Byrne, J. A., & Melcher, R. A. (1996a, 5 November). The best and worst boards: Our new report card on corporate governance. Business Week. http://www.businessweek.com/1996/48/b35031.htm
  • Byrne, J. A., & Melcher, R. A. (1996b, 25 November). What the best boards do. Business Week. http://www.businessweek.com/1996/48/b35033.htm
  • Calabrese, G. G., & Manello, A. (2021). Board diversity and performance in a masculine, aged and glocal supply chain: New empirical evidence. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 21(7), 1440–1459. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-09-2020-0417
  • Carlborg, P., Kindström, D., & Kowalkowski, C. (2014). The evolution of service innovation research: a critical review and synthesis. The Service Industries Journal, 34(5), 373–398. https://doi.org/10.1080/02642069.2013.780044
  • Chouaibi, S., & Affes, H. (2021). The effect of social and ethical practices on environmental disclosure: Evidence from an international ESG data. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 21(7), 1293–1317. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-03-2020-0087
  • Chowdhury, D. (2004). Incentives, control and development: Governance in private and public sector with special reference to Bangladesh. Viswavidyalay Prakashana Samstha.
  • Claessens, S., Djankov, S., & Lang, L. (2000). The separation of ownership and control in East Asian corporations. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1–2), 81–112. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(00)00067-2
  • Central Intelligence Agency (CIA). (2012). The World FactBook. https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/download/download-2012/index.html
  • Claessens, S., Djankov, S., & Lang, L. (1998). Who control East Asian corporations? World Bank.
  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405. https://doi.org/10.2307/2626876
  • Cochran, P. L., Wood, R. A., & Jones, T. B. (1985). The composition of boards of directors and incidence of golden parachutes. Academy of Management Journal, 28(3), 664–671. https://doi.org/10.2307/256121
  • Core, E., Holthausen, R., & Larcker, D. (1999). Corporate governance, chief executive compensation, and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 51(3), 371–406. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(98)00058-0
  • Corey, L. (1930). The House of Morgan. G. Howard Watt.
  • Coughlan, A. T., & Schmidt, R. M. (1985). Executive compensation, management turnover, and firm performance: An empirical investigation. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7(1-3), 43–66. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(85)90027-8
  • Dalton, D. R., Hitt, M. A., Certo, S. T., & Dalton, C. M. (2007). The fundamental agency problem and its mitigation: Independence, equity, and the market for corporate control. Academy of Management Annals, 1(1), 1–64. https://doi.org/10.5465/078559806
  • Dalton, D. R., Daily, C. M., Ellstrand, A. E., & Johnson, J. L. (1998). Meta-analytic reviews of board composition, leadership structure, and financial performance. Strategic Management Journal, 19(3), 269–290. https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(199803)19:3<269::AID-SMJ950>3.0.CO;2-K
  • Driel, H. V. (2019). Financial fraud, scandals, and regulation: A conceptual framework and literature review. Business History, 61(8), 1259–1299.
  • Daryaei, A. A., & Fattahi, Y. (2020). The asymmetric impact of institutional ownership on firm performance: panel smooth transition regression model. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 20(7), 1191–1203. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-06-2020-0254
  • Demsetz, H. (1983). The structure of ownership and the theory of the firm. The Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2), 375–390. https://doi.org/10.1086/467041
  • Dockery, E., Tsegba, IN., & Herbert, W. E. (2012). Does ownership structure influence firm performance? Empirical insights from an emerging market. Journal of Governance and Regulation, 1(4), 165–175. https://doi.org/10.22495/jgr_v1_i4_c1_p4
  • Donadelli, M., Fasan, M., & Magnanelli, B. S. (2014). The agency problem, financial performance and corruption: country, industry and firm level perspectives. European Management Review, 11(3-4), 259–272. https://doi.org/10.1111/emre.12038
  • Drago, R., & Garvey, G. T. (1998). Incentives for helping on the job: Theory and evidence. Journal of Labor Economics, 16(1), 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1086/209880
  • Drucker, P. (1981). What is “business ethics”? The Public Interest, 63, 18–36.
  • Edwards, J. G. (2004). DDT: A case study in scientific fraud. Journal of American Physicians and Surgeons, 9(3), 83–88.
  • Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review. The Academy of Management Review, 14(1), 57–74. https://doi.org/10.2307/258191
  • ElKelish, W. W. (2018). Corporate governance risk and the agency problem. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 18(2), 254–269. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-08-2017-0195
  • Eun, C., Resnick, B., & Brean, D. (2004). International financial management (3rd ed.). The McGraw-Hill Companies Inc.
  • Fama, E. F. (1980). Agency problems and the theory of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 88(2), 288–307. https://doi.org/10.1086/260866
  • Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983). Separation of ownership and control. The Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2), 301–325. https://doi.org/10.1086/467037
  • Farooq, M., Noor, A., & Ali, S. (2022). Corporate governance and firm performance: empirical evidence from Pakistan. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 22(1), 42–66. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-07-2020-0286
  • Fenn, G., & Liang, N. (2001). Corporate pay-out policy and managerial stock incentives. Journal of Financial Economics, 60(1), 45–72. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(01)00039-3
  • Fernández-Temprano, M. A., & Tejerina-Gaite, F. (2020). Types of director, board diversity and firm performance. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 20(2), 324–342. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-03-2019-0096
  • Fernie, S., & Metcalf, D. (1999). It’s not what you pay it’s the way that you pay it and that’s what gets results: Jockeys’ pay and performance. LABOUR, 13(2), 385–411. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9914.00100
  • Flood Museum, J. (2013). An overview of the 1889 tragedy. https://www.jaha.org/attractions/johnstown-flood-museum/flood-history/
  • Folsom, B.Jr. (2008). New deal or raw deal?: How FDR’s economic legacy has damaged America. Threshold Editions, NY.
  • Friedman, M. (1970, September 13). The social responsibility of business is to increase its profits. The New York Times Magazine. http://www.francodebenedetti.it/http://www.francodebenedetti.it/wp-content/uploads/Friedman-The-Social-Responsibility-of-Business-is-to-Increase-its-Profits.pdf
  • Galbraith, J. K. (1967). The new industrial state. Houghton-Mifflin.
  • Galbraith, J. K. (1977). The age of uncertainty: A history of economic ideas and their consequences. Houghton Mifflin.
  • García-Meca, E., & Sánchez-Ballesta, J. (2009). Corporate governance and earnings management: A meta-analysis. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17(5), 594–610. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2009.00753.x
  • Governmental Accounting Standards Board (GASB). ( 2013). Facts about GASB. http://www.gasb.org/cs/BlobServer?blobkey=id&blobnocache=true&blobwhere=1175827287722&blobheader=application/pdf&blobheadername2=ContentLength&blobheadername1= Content-Disposition&blobheadervalue2=744409&blobheadervalue1=filename%3DFacts_ about_GASB_%282013-2014%29.pdf&blobcol=urldata&blobtable=MungoBlobs
  • Gates, B. (1996). The road ahead. Penguin, Harmondsworth.
  • Gedajlovic, E., & Shapiro, D. M. (2002). Ownership structure and firm profitability in Japan. The Academy of Management Journal, 45(3), 565–575. https://doi.org/10.2307/3069381
  • Gordon, D. M. (1996). Fat and mean: The corporate squeeze of working Americans and the myth of managerial downsizing. Free Press.
  • Government UK. (2013). Whistleblowing. https://www.gov.uk/whistleblowing/dismissals-and-whistleblowing
  • Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. (1986). The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94(4), 691–719. https://doi.org/10.1086/261404
  • Grossman, S., & Hart, O. (1983). An analysis of the principal–agent problem. Econometrica, 51(1), 7–45. https://doi.org/10.2307/1912246
  • Guizani, M., & Abdalkrim, G. (2021). Ownership structure and audit quality: the mediating effect of board independence. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 21(5), 754–774. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-12-2019-0369
  • Guluma, T. F. (2021). The impact of corporate governance measures on firm performance: the influences of managerial overconfidence. Future Business Journal, 7(1), 50. https://doi.org/10.1186/s43093-021-00093-6
  • Hall, B. J., & Liebman, J. B. (1998). Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(3), 653–691. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355398555702
  • Hanazaki, M., & Horiuchi, A. (2003). A review of Japan’s bank crisis from the governance perspective. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 11(3), 305–325. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0927-538X(03)00026-X
  • Hartzell, J., & Starks, L. (2003). Institutional investors and executive compensation. The Journal of Finance, 58(6), 2351–2374. https://doi.org/10.1046/j.1540-6261.2003.00608.x
  • Holderness, C. G., & Sheehan, D. P. (1988). The role of majority shareholders in publicly held corporations: An exploratory analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 20(1-2), 317–346. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(88)90049-9
  • Holderness, C. G., Kroszner, R. S., & Sheehan, D. P. (1999). Were the good old days that good? Changes in managerial stock ownership since the Great Depression. The Journal of Finance, 54(2), 435–469. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00114
  • Hsu, S., Lin, S.-W., Chen, W.-P., & Huang, J.-W. (2021). CEO duality, information costs, and firm performance. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 55, 101011. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2019.101011
  • Iga, M., & Auerbach, M. (1977). Political corruption and social structure in Japan. Asian Survey, 17(6), 556–564. https://doi.org/10.2307/2643156
  • Issa, A., Yousef, H., Bakry, A., Hanaysha, J. R., & Sahyouni, A. (2021). Does the board diversity impact bank performance in the MENA countries? A multilevel study. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 21(5), 865–891. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-06-2020-0222
  • James, D. R., & Soref, M. (1981). Profit constraints on managerial autonomy: Managerial theory and the unmaking of the corporation president. American Sociological Review, 46(1), 1–18. https://doi.org/10.2307/2095023
  • Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X
  • Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990). Performance pay and top-management incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 98(2), 225–264. https://doi.org/10.1086/261677
  • Jin, X., Xu, L., Xin, Y., & Adhikari, A. (2022). Political governance in China’s state-owned enterprises. China Journal of Accounting Research, 15Issue(2), 100236. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cjar.2022.100236
  • Johnson, S., Boone, P., Breach, A., & Friedman, E. (2000). Corporate governance in the Asian financial crisis. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1–2), 141–186. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(00)00069-6
  • Johnson, V. R. (2019). The fiduciary obligations of public officials. St. Mary’s Journal on Legal Malpractice & Ethics, 9(2), 298–340.
  • Jovanova, M. (2014). Internal audit as a service of management for improvement of economic efficiency of the enterprises in Republic of Macedonia [MA thesis]. Faculty of Economics, Prilep, Macedonia.
  • Kamerschen, D. R. (1968). The influence of ownership and control on profit rates. American Economic Review, 58(3), 432–447.
  • Kang, J.-K., & Shivdasani, A. (1995). Firm performance, corporate governance, and top executive turnover in Japan. Journal of Financial Economics, 38(1), 29–58. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(94)00807-D
  • Kaplan, S. (1994a). Top executive rewards and firm performance: A comparison of Japan and the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 102(3), 510–546. https://doi.org/10.1086/261944
  • Kaplan, S. (1994b). Top executives, turnover, and firm performance in Germany. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 10(1), 142–159. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/10.1.142
  • Kong, D., Zhu, L., & Wang, X. (2022). Anti-corruption and CEO compensation: Evidence from a natural experiment in China. Economic Modelling, 106, 105697. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2021.105697
  • Kosnik, R. D. (1987). Greenmail: A study of board performance in corporate governance. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32(2), 163–185. https://doi.org/10.2307/2393124
  • Krugman, P. (2009). The return of depression economics and the crisis of 2008. W.W. Norton Company Limited.
  • Krugman, P. R., Dominquez, K. M., & Rogoff, K. (1998). It’s Baaack: Japan’s slump and the return of the liquidity trap. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1998(2), 137–205. https://doi.org/10.2307/2534694
  • Lan, L. L., & Heracleous, L. (2010). Rethinking agency theory: The view from law. Academy of Management Review, 35(2), 294–314. https://doi.org/10.5465/AMR.2010.48463335
  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (1999). Corporate ownership around the world. The Journal of Finance, 54(2), 471–517. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00115
  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1998). Corporate ownership around the world. NBER Working Paper Series No. 6625. National Bureau of Economic Research.
  • Ladd, J, The. (1970). Morality and the ideal of rationality in formal organizations. Monist, 54(4), 488–516. https://doi.org/10.5840/monist197054433
  • Larcker, D., & Tayan, B. (2011). Corporate governance matters: A closer look at organizational choices and their consequences. Pearson Education Inc.
  • Larner, R. J. (1970). Management control and the large corporation. Dunellen.
  • Leland, H. (1998). Agency Costs, Risk Management, and Capital Structure. The Journal of Finance, 53(4), 1213–1243. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00051
  • Leicht, K. T., & Brady, D. (2012). Testing the fat and mean thesis: Managerial intensity and earnings inequality in affluent democracies. Research in the Sociology of Work, 22, 141–168.
  • Li, S. (2020). A review of the relationship between agency cost and corporate investment efficiency. American Journal of Industrial and Business Management, 10(04), 734–748. https://doi.org/10.4236/ajibm.2020.104050
  • Lim, E. W. K. (2021). Concentrated ownership, state-owned enterprises and corporate governance. Oxford Journal of Legal Studies, 41(3), 663–691. https://doi.org/10.1093/ojls/gqaa050
  • Lomborg, B. (2001). The skeptical environmentalist: Measuring the real state of the world. Cambridge University Press.
  • Mabrey, D. (2007). Lockheed bribery scandal. In J. Gerber & E. L. Jensen (Eds.), Encyclopedia of white-collar crime (pp. 175–177). Greenwood Press.
  • Mace, M. (1965). The president and corporate planning. Harvard Business Review, 43(1), 49–62.
  • Mace, M. (1977). Strengthening the functions of internal auditors. Harvard Business Review, 55, 46–47.
  • Mace, M. (1972). The president and the board of directors. Harvard Business Review, 50(12), 37–49.
  • Main, B. G. M., Bruce, A., & Buck, T. (1996). Total board remuneration and company performance. The Economic Journal, 106(439), 1627–1644. https://doi.org/10.2307/2235204
  • Martin, M. W., & Schinzinger, R. (2004). Ethics in engineering. McGraw-Hill.
  • Marx, K. (1974). Kapital. Edited by Frederick Engels; translated from the 3rd German ed. by Samuel Moore and Edward Aveling. Lawrence and Wishart.
  • Maslow, A. H. (1968). Toward a psychology of being. D. Van Nostrand Company.
  • Mathew, S., Ibrahim, S., & Archbold, S. (2020). Corporate governance and firm risk. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 18(1), 52–67. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-02-2017-0024
  • Masulis, R., Wang, C., & Xie, F. (2009). Agency problems at dual-class companies. The Journal of Finance, 64(4), 1697–1727. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01477.x
  • McColl-Kennedy, J. R., Snyder, H., Elg, M., Witell, L., Helkkula, A., Hogan, S. J., & Anderson, L. (2017). The changing role of the health care customer: Review, synthesis and research agenda. Journal of Service Management, 28(1), 2–33. https://doi.org/10.1108/JOSM-01-2016-0018
  • McLean, B. (2001, March 5). Is Enron overpriced? Fortune Magazine. http://money.cnn.com/2006/01/13/news/companies/enronoriginal_fortune/index.htm
  • McLean, B., & Elkind, P. (2004). The smartest guys in the room: The amazing rise and scandalous fall of Enron. Penguin Group.
  • Mehmood, R., Hunjra, A. I., & Chani, M. I. (2019). The impact of corporate diversification and financial structure on firm performance: Evidence from South Asian countries. Journal of Risk and Financial Management, 12(1), 49. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12010049
  • Mizruchi, M. S. (2004). Berle and Means revisited: The governance and power of large U.S. corporations. Theory and Society, 33(5), 579–617. https://doi.org/10.1023/B:RYSO.0000045757.93910.ed
  • Monsen, R. J., Chiu, J. S., & Cooley, D. E. (1968). The effect of separation of ownership and control on the performance of the large firm. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82(3), 435–451. https://doi.org/10.2307/1879516
  • Morck, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1988). Management ownership and market valuation: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 20(1–2), 293–315. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(88)90048-7
  • Moyo, D. (2010). Dead aid: Why aid is not working and how there is another way for Africa. Penguin, Harmondsworth.
  • Munisi, G., Hermes, N., & Randøy, T. (2014). Corporate boards and ownership structure: Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. International Business Review, 23(4), 785–796. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ibusrev.2013.12.001
  • Murphy, K. J. (1985). Corporate performance and managerial remuneration: An empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7(1–3), 11–42. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(85)90026-6
  • Ndofor, H. A., Wesley, C., & Priem, R. L. (2015). Providing CEOs with opportunities to cheat: The effects of complexity-based information asymmetries on financial reporting fraud. Journal of Management, 41(6), 1774–1797. https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206312471395
  • Nguyen, A. H., Doan, D. T., & Nguyen, L. H. (2020). Corporate governance and agency cost: Empirical evidence from Vietnam. Journal of Risk and Financial Management, 13(5), 103.
  • O’Connor, J. P., Jr., Priem, R. L., Coombs, J. E., & Gilley, K. M. (2006). Do CEO stock options prevent or promote fraudulent financial reporting? Academy of Management Journal, 49(3), 483–500. https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2006.21794666
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). (2019). Corporate Governance Factbook 2019. OECD.
  • Ogabo, B., Ogar, G., & Nuipoko, T. (2021). Ownership structure and firm performance: The role of managerial and institutional ownership-evidence from the UK. American Journal of Industrial and Business Management, 11(07), 859–886. https://doi.org/10.4236/ajibm.2021.117053
  • Orbach, B., & Campbell Rebling, G. E. (2012, May 17). The antitrust curse of bigness. 85 Southern California Law Review 605; Arizona Legal Studies Discussion Paper No. 11–23. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1856553
  • Pagano, M., Panetta, F., & Zingales, L. (1998). Why do companies go public? An empirical analysis. The Journal of Finance, 53(1), 27–64. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.25448
  • Palmatier, R. W., Houston, M. B., & Hulland, J. (2018). Review articles: Purpose, process, and structure. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 46(1), 1–5. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-017-0563-4
  • Palmer, J. (1973). The profit-performance effects of the separation of ownership from control in large U.S. Industrial corporations. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 4(1), 293–303. https://doi.org/10.2307/3003151
  • Pandey, K. D., & Sahu, T. N. (2021). Ownership concentration and agency crises in Indian manufacturing firms. Business Perspectives and Research, 9(1), 128–143. https://doi.org/10.1177/2278533720910842
  • Panda, B., & Leepsa, N. M. (2017). Agency theory: Review of theory and evidence on problems and perspectives. Indian Journal of Corporate Governance, 10(1), 74–95. https://doi.org/10.1177/0974686217701467
  • Pathan, S. (2009). Strong boards, CEO power and bank risk-taking. Journal of Banking & Finance, 33(7), 1340–1350. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.02.001
  • Rhoades, D. L., Rechner, P. L., & Sundaramurthy, C. (2000). Board composition and financial performance: A meta-analysis of the influence of outside directors. Journal of Managerial Issues, 12(1), 76–91.
  • Rosenstein, S., & Wyatt, J. G. (1990). Outside directors, board independence and shareholder wealth. Journal of Financial Economics, 26(2), 175–191. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(90)90002-H
  • Ross, S. (1973). The economic theory of agency: The principal’s problem. American Economic Review, 63(2), 134–139.
  • Rowlinson, M., Toms, S., & Wilson, J. (2006). Legitimacy and the capitalist corporation: Cross-cutting perspectives on ownership and control. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 17(5), 681–702. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cpa.2003.10.006
  • Schwarcz, S. L. (2008). Markets, systemic risk, and the subprime mortgage crisis. Southern Methodist University Law Review, 61(2), 209–217.
  • Selarka, E. (2005). Ownership concentration and firm value: A study from the Indian corporate sector. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 41(6), 83–108. https://doi.org/10.1080/1540496X.2005.11052627
  • Securities Exchange Commission (SEC). (2013). What we do. http://www.sec.gov/about/whatwedo.shtml
  • Sehrawat, N. K., Kumar, A., Lohia, N., Bansal, S., & Agarwal, T. (2019). Impact of corporate governance on earnings management: Large sample evidence from India. Asian Economic and Financial Review, 9(12), 1335–1345. https://doi.org/10.18488/journal.aefr.2019.912.1335.1345
  • Shakir, R. (2008). Effect of block ownership on performance of Malaysian property companies. Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, 14(4), 361–382. https://doi.org/10.1080/14445921.2008.11104263
  • Shil, N. C., & Chowdhury, A. (2024). Pathways to consolidate corporate governance by incorporating gaps in management accounting practices: An integrative literature review research approach. IIMS Journal of Management Science, 15(1), 67–88. https://doi.org/10.1177/0976030X231226018
  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1986). Large shareholders and corporate control. Journal of Political Economy, 94(3, Part 1), 461–488. https://doi.org/10.1086/261385
  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. The Journal of Finance, 52(2), 737–783. https://doi.org/10.2307/2329497
  • Sikka, P., & Stittle, J. (2019). Debunking the myth of shareholder ownership of companies: Some implications for corporate governance and financial reporting. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 63, 101992. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cpa.2017.03.011
  • Simkovic, M. (2013). Competition and crisis in mortgage securitization. Indiana Law Journal, 88(1), 213–271.
  • Singh, A. (2003). Competition, corporate governance and selection in emerging markets. The Economic Journal, 113(491), F443–F464. https://doi.org/10.1046/j.0013-0133.2003.00164.x
  • Snyder, H., Witell, L., Gustafsson, A., Fombelle, P., & Kristensson, P. (2016). Identifying categories of service innovation: A review and synthesis of the literature. Journal of Business Research, 69(7), 2401–2408. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2016.01.009
  • Snyder, H. (2019). Literature review as a research methodology: An overview and guidelines. Journal of Business Research, 104(1), 333–339. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2019.07.039
  • Steyn, B., & Stainbank, L. (2013). Separation of ownership and control in South-African Listed Companies. South African Journal of Economic and Management Sciences, 16(3), 316–345. https://doi.org/10.4102/sajems.v16i3.418
  • Stigler, G. J. (1958). The economies of scale. The Journal of Law & Economics, 1(1), 54–71. https://doi.org/10.1086/466541
  • Torraco, R. J. (2016). Writing integrative literature reviews: Using the past and present to explore the future. Human Resource Development Review, 15(4), 404–428. https://doi.org/10.1177/1534484316671606
  • Tran, H. T. (2021). The link between independent directors and firm’s performance: the moderating role of corporate social responsibility. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 21(5), 831–844. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-05-2020-0176
  • Tran, N. H., & Le, C. D. (2020). Ownership concentration, corporate risk-taking and performance: Evidence from Vietnamese listed firms. Cogent Economics & Finance, 8(1), 1732640. https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2020.1732640
  • Transparency International. (2012a). Transparency in corporate reporting: Assessing the world’s largest companies. http://www.transparency.org/whatwedo/pub/transparency_in_corporate_reporting_assessing_the_worlds_largest_companies
  • Transparency International. (2012b). Corruption and the financial sector. http://www.transparency.org/news/feature/scandals_show_urgent_need_for_bank_reform
  • Tullock, G. (1997). Where is the rectangle? Public Choice, 91(2), 149–159. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1004984432682
  • Ullah, I., Fang, H., & Jebran, K. (2019). Do gender diversity and CEO gender enhance firm’s value? Evidence from an emerging economy. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 20(1), 44–66. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-03-2019-0085
  • U.S. Department of Justice. (1995). Occidental to pay $129 million in Love Canal settlement. http://www.justice.gov/opa/pr/Pre_96/December95/638.txt.html
  • Vadasi, C., Bekiaris, M., & Andrikopoulos, A. (2019). Corporate governance and internal audit: an institutional theory perspective. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 20(1), 175–190. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-07-2019-0215
  • Vairavan, A., & Zhang, G. P. (2020). Does a diverse board matter? A mediation analysis of board racial diversity and firm performance. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 20(7), 1223–1241. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-02-2020-0081
  • Verlegh, P. W. J., & Steenkamp, J.-B. (1999). A review and meta-analysis of country-of-origin research. Journal of Economic Psychology, 20(5), 521–546. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-4870(99)00023-9
  • Wallace, J. (1993). Hard drive: Bill Gates and the making of the Microsoft empire. Harper Business.
  • Wawrosz, P. (2022). How corruption is and should be investigated by economic theory. Economies, 10(12), 326. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10120326
  • Wesley, C. L., & Ndofor, H. A. (2013). The great escape: The unaddressed ethical issue of investor responsibility for corporate malfeasance. Business Ethics Quarterly, 23(3), 443–475. https://doi.org/10.5840/beq201323328
  • Westerfield, R., & Jaffe, J. (2008). Corporate finance. The McGraw – Hill Companies, Inc.
  • Whalen, R. C. (2008). The subprime crisis—cause, effect and consequences. Journal of Affordable Housing & Community Development Law, 17(3), 219–235.
  • Whittemore, R., & Knafl, K. (2005). The integrative review: Updated methodology. Journal of Advanced Nursing, 52(5), 546–553. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1365-2648.2005.03621.x
  • Wildavsky, A. (1995). But is it true? A citizen’s guide to environmental health and safety issues. Harvard University Press.
  • Witell, L., Snyder, H., Gustafsson, A., Fombelle, P., & Kristensson, P. (2016). Defining service innovation: a review and synthesis. Journal of Business Research, 69(8), 2863–2872. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2015.12.055
  • Wormser, I. M. (1933). Review of Adolf A. Berle, Jr. and Gardiner C. Means “The modern corporation and private property”. American Bar Association Journal, 113, 514–516.
  • Wu, X. (2005). Corporate governance and corruption: A cross-country analysis. Governance, 18(2), 151–170. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0491.2005.00271.x
  • Wulandari, T. R., & Setiawan, D. (2021). Ownership concentration, foreign ownership and tunneling in Indonesia. Rajagiri Management Journal, 17(1), 21–36. https://doi.org/10.1108/RAMJ-12-2020-0068
  • Yamamura, K. (1977). Success illgotten? The role of Meiji militarism in Japan’s technological progress. The Journal of Economic History, 37(1), 113–135. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050700096777
  • Yu, X., Zhang, P., & Zheng, Y. (2015). Corporate governance, political connections, and intra-industry effects: Evidence from corporate Scandals in China. Financial Management, 44(1), 49–80. https://doi.org/10.1111/fima.12064
  • Yusof, N. Z. M. (2016). Context matters: A critique of agency theory in corporate governance research in emerging countries. International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, 6(S7), 154–158.
  • Yusuf, F., Yousaf, A., & Saeed, A. (2018). Rethinking agency theory in developing countries: A case study of Pakistan. Accounting Forum, 42(4), 281–292.
  • Zingales, L. (1994). The value of the voting right: A study of the Milan Stock Exchange experience. Review of Financial Studies, 7(1), 125–148. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/7.1.125