1,894
Views
1
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

Counterfactual-based nudging and signaling promote more efficient coordination during group tasks

, &
Pages 98-124 | Received 31 May 2019, Accepted 04 Dec 2020, Published online: 11 Jan 2021

References

  • Beard, T. R., & Beil, R. O. (1994). Do people rely on the self-interested maximization of others? An experimental test. Management Science, 40(2), 252–262. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.40.2.252
  • Berninghaus, S. K., & Ehrhart, K.-M. (1998). Time horizon and equilibrium selection in tacit coordination games: Experimental results. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 37(2), 231–248. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(98)00086-9
  • Blume, A., DeJong, D. V., Kim, Y. G., & Sprinkle, G. B. (1998). Experimental evidence on the evolution of meaning of messages in sender-receiver games. The American Economic Review, 88(5), 1323–1340. https://www.jstor.org/stable/116874
  • Bortolotti, S., Devetag, G., & Ortmann, A. (2016). Group incentives or individual incentives? A real-effort weak-link experiment. Journal of Economic Psychology, 56, 60–73. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2016.05.004
  • Bosworth, S. J. (2013). Social capital and equilibrium selection in Stag Hunt games. Journal of Economic Psychology, 39, 11–20. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2013.06.004
  • Brandts, J., & Cooper, D. J. (2006). A change would do you good …. An Experimental Study on How to Overcome Coordination Failure in Organizations. American Economic Review, 96(3), 669–693. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.96.3.669
  • Brandts, J., Cooper, D. J., Fatas, E., & Qi, S. (2015). Stand by me—experiments on help and commitment in coordination games. Management Science, 62(10), 2916–2936. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2269
  • Brandts, J., Cooper, D. J., & Weber, R. A. (2014). Legitimacy, communication, and leadership in the turnaround game. Management Science, 61(11), 2627–2645. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2014.2021
  • Byrne, R. M. (2016). Counterfactual thought. Annual Review of Psychology, 67(1), 135–157. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-psych-122414-033249
  • Cachon, G. P., & Camerer, C. F. (1996). Loss-avoidance and forward induction in experimental coordination games. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(1), 165–194. https://doi.org/10.2307/2946661
  • Cacioppo, J. T., & Petty, R. E. (1982). The need for cognition. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 42(1), 116–131. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.42.1.116
  • Camerer, C., & Ho, T. H. (1998). Experience-weighted attraction learning in coordination games: Probability rules, heterogeneity, and time-variation. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 42(2–3), 305–326. https://doi.org/10.1006/jmps.1998.1217
  • Camerer, C., & Ho, T. H. (1999). Experience‐weighted attraction learning in normal form games. Econometrica, 67(4), 827–874. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00054
  • Camerer, C. F. (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction. Russell Sage Foundation.
  • Charness, G., Gneezy, U., & Henderson, A. (2018). Experimental methods: Measuring effort in economics experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 149, 74–87. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2018.02.024
  • Chaudhuri, A., Schotter, A., & Sopher, B. (2009). Talking ourselves to efficiency: Coordination in inter‐generational minimum effort games with private, almost common and common knowledge of advice. The Economic Journal, 119(534), 91–122. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2008.02207.x
  • Chen, D. L., Schonger, M., & Wickens, C. (2016). oTree—An open-source platform for laboratory, online, and field experiments. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 9, 88–97. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2015.12.001
  • Collins, M. G., Juvina, I., & Gluck, K. A. (2016). Cognitive model of trust dynamics predicts human behavior within and between two games of strategic interaction with computerized confederate agents. Frontiers in Psychology, 7, 49. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2016.00049
  • Cooper, D. J., & Van Huyck, J. (2018). Coordination and transfer. Experimental Economics, 21(3), 487–512. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9521-8
  • Cooper, R., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1994). Alternative institutions for resolving coordination problems: Experimental evidence on forward induction and preplaycommunication. In J. W. Friedman (Ed.), Problems of coordination in economic activity (pp. 129–146). Springer.
  • Cooper, R., De Jong, D., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. (1992). Communication in coordination games. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 739–771. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118488
  • Cooper, R. W., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1990). Selection criteria in coordination games: Some experimental results. The American Economic Review, 80(1), 218–233. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2006744
  • Costa-Gomes, M. A., Crawford, V. P., & Iriberri, N. (2009). Comparing models of strategic thinking in Van Huyck, Battalio, and Beil’s coordination games. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(2–3), 365–376. https://doi.org/10.1162/JEEA.2009.7.2-3.365
  • Devetag, G., & Ortmann, A. (2007). When and why? A critical survey on coordination failure in the laboratory. Experimental Economics, 10(3), 331–344. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-007-9178-9
  • Dornic, S., Ekehammar, B., & Laaksonen, T. (1991). Tolerance for mental effort: Self-ratings related to perception, performance and personality. Personality and Individual Differences, 12(3), 313–319. https://doi.org/10.1016/0191-8869(91)90118-U
  • Duffy, J., & Nagel, R. (1997). On the robustness of behaviour in experimental ‘beauty contest’games. The Economic Journal, 107(445), 1684–1700. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.1997.tb00075.x
  • Dyczewski, E. A., & Markman, K. D. (2012). General attainability beliefs moderate the motivational effects of counterfactual thinking. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 48(5), 1217–1220. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jesp.2012.04.016
  • Ekkekakis, P., Hall, E. E., & Petruzzello, S. J. (2005). Some like It vigorous: Measuring individual differences in the preference for and tolerance of exercise Intensity. Journal of Sport and Exercise Psychology, 27(3), 350–374. https://doi.org/10.1123/jsep.27.3.350
  • Engelmann, D., & Normann, H. T. (2010). Maximum effort in the minimum-effort game. Experimental Economics, 13(3), 249–259. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-010-9239-3
  • Epstude, K., & Roese, N. J. (2008). The functional theory of counterfactual thinking. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 12(2), 168–192. https://doi.org/10.1177/1088868308316091
  • Faul, F., Erdfelder, E., Buchner, A., & Lang, A.-G. (2009). Statistical power analyses using G*Power 3.1: Tests for correlation and regression analyses. Behavior Research Methods, 41(4), 1149–1160. https://doi.org/10.3758/BRM.41.4.1149
  • Faul, F., Erdfelder, E., Lang, A.-G., & Buchner, A. (2007). G*Power 3: A flexible statistical power analysis program for the social, behavioral, and biomedical sciences. Behavior Research Methods, 39(2), 175–191. https://doi.org/10.3758/BF03193146
  • Florack, A., Keller, J., & Palcu, J. (2013). Regulatory focus in economic contexts. Journal Of Economic Psychology, 38(C), 127–137. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2013.06.001
  • Galinksy, A. D., & Moskowitz, G. B. (2000). Counterfactuals as behavior primes: Priming the simulation heuristic and consideration of alternatives. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 36(4), 257–383. https://doi.org/10.1006/jesp.1999.1409
  • Galinksy, A. D., Moskowitz, G. B., & Skurnik, I. (2000). Counterfactuals as self-generated primes: The effect of prior counterfactual activation on person perception judgments. Social Cognition, 18(3), 252–280. https://doi.org/10.1521/soco.2000.18.3.252
  • Gilovich, T. (1983). Biased evaluation and persistence in gambling. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 44(6), 1110. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.44.6.1110
  • Haruvy, E., & Stahl, D. O. (2007). Equilibrium selection and bounded rationality in symmetric normal-form games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 62(1), 98–119. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2005.05.002
  • Ho, T. H., Camerer, C., & Weigelt, K. (1998). Iterated dominance and iterated best response in experimental” p-beauty contests”. The American Economic Review, 88(4), 947–969. https://www.jstor.org/stable/117013
  • Ho, T. H., & Weigelt, K. (1996). Task complexity, equilibrium selection, and learning: An experimental study. Management Science, 42(5), 659–679. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.42.5.659
  • Hur, T. (2001). The role of regulatory focus in activation of counterfactual thinking. Korean Journal of Social and Personality Psychology, 15, 159–171.
  • Jackson, J. J., Wood, D., Bogg, T., Walton, K. E., Harms, P. D., & Roberts, B. W. (2010). What do conscientious people do? Development and validation of the Behavioral Indicators of Conscientiousness (BIC). Journal of Research in Personality, 44(4), 501–511. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jrp.2010.06.005
  • Juvina, I., Nador, J., Larue, O., Green, R., Harel, A., & Minnery, B. (2018). Measuring individual differences in cognitive effort avoidance. In Proceedings of the 40th Annual Meeting of the Cognitive Science Society, Madison, WI.
  • Kahneman, D., & Miller, D. T. (1986). Norm theory: Comparing reality to its alternatives. Psychological Review, 93(2), 136. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.93.2.136
  • Kool, W., McGuire, J. T., Rosen, Z. B., & Botvinick, M. M. (2010). Decision making and the avoidance of cognitive demand. Journal of Experimental Psychology. General, 139(4), 665–682. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0020198
  • Kray, L. J., & Galinsky, A. D. (2003). The debiasing effect of counterfactual mind-set: Increasing the search for disconfirmatory information in group decisions. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 91(1), 69–81. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0749-5978(02)00534-4
  • Krueger, C., & Tian, L. (2004). A comparison of the general linear mixed model and repeated measures ANOVA using a dataset with multiple missing data points. Biological Research for Nursing, 6(2), 151–157. https://doi.org/10.1177/1099800404267682
  • Leng, A., Friesen, L., Kalayci, K., & Man, P. (2018). A minimum effort coordination game experiment in continuous time. Experimental Economics, 21(3), 549–572. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9550-3
  • Lieberman, M. D., Gaunt, R., Gilbert, D. T., & Trope, Y. (2002). Reflection and reflexion: A social cognitive neuroscience approach to attributional inference. In M. P. Zanna (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 34, pp. 199–249). Academic Press.
  • Malone, T. W., & Crowston, K. (1994). The interdisciplinary study of coordination. ACM Computing Surveys (CSUR), 26(1), 87–119. https://doi.org/10.1145/174666.174668
  • Markman, K. D., Gavanski, I., Sherman, S. J., & McMullen, M. N. (1993). The mental simulation of better and worse possible worlds. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 29(1), 87–109. https://doi.org/10.1006/jesp.1993.1005
  • Markman, K. D., & McMullen, M. N. (2003). A reflection and evaluation model of comparative thinking. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 7(3), 244–267. https://doi.org/10.1207/S15327957PSPR0703_04
  • Markman, K. D., McMullen, M. N., & Elizaga, R. A. (2008). Counterfactual thinking, persistence, and performance: A test of the reflection and evaluation model. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 44(2), 421–428. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jesp.2007.01.001
  • McKelvey, R. D., & Palfrey, T. R. (1992). An experimental study of the centipede game. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 60(4), 803–836. https://doi.org/10.2307/2951567
  • Mehta, J., Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (1994). The nature of salience: An experimental investigation of pure coordination games. The American Economic Review, 84(3), 658–673. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2118074
  • Morris, M., & Moore, P. C. (2000). The lessons we (don’t) learn: Counterfactual thinking and organizational accountability after a close call. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45, 737–765.
  • Nagel, R. (1995). Unraveling in guessing games: An experimental study. The American Economic Review, 85(5), 1313–1326. https://doi.org/10.2307/2667018
  • Nasco, S. A., & Marsh, K. L. (1999). Gaining control through counterfactual thinking. Personality & Social Psychology Bulletin, 25(5), 556–568. https://doi.org/10.1177/0146167299025005002
  • Offerman, T. (2002). Hurting hurts more than helping helps. European Economic Review, 46(8), 1423–1437. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00176-3
  • Riechmann, T., & Weimann, J. (2008). Competition as a coordination device: Experimental evidence from a minimum effort coordination game. European Journal of Political Economy, 24(2), 437–454. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2007.09.004
  • Rim, S., & Summerville, A. (2014). How far to the road not taken? The effect of psychological distance on counterfactual direction. Personality & Social Psychology Bulletin, 40(3), 391–401. https://doi.org/10.1177/0146167213513304
  • Roese, N. J. (1994). The functional basis of counterfactual thinking. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 66(5), 805–818. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.66.5.805
  • Roese, N. J. (1997). Counterfactual thinking. Psychological Bulletin, 121(1), 133–148. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-2909.121.1.133
  • Roese, N. J., & Olson, J. M. (1997). Counterfactual thinking: The intersection of affect and function. In M. P. Zanna (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 29, pp. 1–59). Academic Press.
  • Roese, N. J., & Epstude, K. (2017). The functional theory of counterfactual thinking: New evidence, new challenges, new insights. In J. M. Olson (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 56, pp. 1–79). Academic Press.
  • Roese, N. J., & Hur, T. (1997). Affective determinants in counterfactual thinking. Social Cognition, 15(4), 274–290. https://doi.org/10.1521/soco.1997.15.4.274
  • Roese, N. J., Hur, T., & Pennington, G. L. (1999). Counterfactual thinking and regulatory focus: Implications for action versus inaction and sufficiency versus necessity. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 77(6), 1109. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.77.6.1109
  • Rubinstein, A. (1989). The electronic mail game: Strategic behavior under” Almost common knowledge”. The American Economic Review, 79(3), 385–391.
  • Rydval, O., & Ortmann, A. (2005). Loss avoidance as selection principle: Evidence from simple stag-hunt games. Economics Letters, 88(1), 101–107. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2004.12.027
  • Sahin, S. G., Eckel, C., & Komai, M. (2015). An experimental study of leadership institutions in collective action games. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 100–113. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40881-015-0010-6
  • Sanna, L. J., & Turley, K. J. (1996). Antecedents to spontaneous counterfactual thinking: Effects of expectancy violation and outcome valence. Personality & Social Psychology Bulletin, 22(9), 906–919. https://doi.org/10.1177/0146167296229005
  • Sanna, L. J., & Turley-Ames, K. J. (2000). Counterfactual intensity. European Journal of Social Psychology, 30(2), 273–296. https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1099-0992(200003/04)30:2<273::AID-EJSP993>3.0.CO;2-Y
  • Schotter, A., Weigelt, K., & Wilson, C. (1994). A laboratory investigation of multiperson rationality and presentation effects. Games and Economic Behavior, 6(3), 445–468. https://doi.org/10.1006/game.1994.1026
  • Schwarz, N. (1990). Feelings as information: Informational and motivational functions of affective states. In E. T. Higgins & R. M. Sorrentino (Eds.), Handbook of motivation and cognition: Foundations of social behavior (Vol. 2, pp. 527–561). Guilford Press.
  • Schwarz, N., & Clore, G. L. (1983). Mood, misattribution, and judgments of well-being: Informative and directive functions of affective states. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 45(3), 513–523. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.45.3.513
  • Shenhav, A., Rand, D. G., & Greene, J. D. (2017). The relationship between intertemporal choice and following the path of least resistance across choices, preferences, and beliefs. Judgment and Decision Making, 12(1), 1–18. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2724547
  • Smallman, R., & Summerville, A. (2018). Counterfactual thought in reasoning and performance. Social and Personality Psychology Compass, 12(4), e12376. https://doi.org/10.1111/spc3.12376
  • Tangney, J. P., Baumeister, R. F., & Boone, A. L. (2004). High self‐control predicts good adjustment, less pathology, better grades, and interpersonal success. Journal of Personality, 72(2), 271–324. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0022-3506.2004.00263.x
  • Taylor, S. E. (1991). Asymmetrical effects of positive and negative events: The mobilization-minimization hypothesis. Psychological Bulletin, 110,(1), 67–85. https://psycnet.apa.org/buy/1991-32481-001
  • Thaler, R. H., Sunstein, C. R., & Balz, J. P. (2013). Choice architecture. In E. Shafir (Ed.), The behavioral foundations of public policy (pp. 428–439). Princeton University Press.
  • Van Huyck, J. B., Battalio, R. C., & Beil, R. O. (1990). Tacit coordination games, strategic uncertainty, and coordination failure. The American Economic Review, 80(1), 234–248. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2006745
  • Van Huyck, J. B., Battalio, R. C., & Beil, R. O. (1991). Strategic uncertainty, equilibrium selection, and coordination failure in average opinion games. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(3), 885–910. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937932
  • Van Huyck, J. B., Battalio, R. C., & Beil, R. O. (1993). Asset markets as an equilibrium selection mechanism: Coordination failure, game form auctions, and tacit communication. Games and Economic Behavior, 5(3), 485–504. https://doi.org/10.1006/game.1993.1026
  • Van Huyck, J. B., Battalio, R. C., & Rankin, F. W. (2007). Evidence on learning in coordination games. Experimental Economics, 10(3), 205–220. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-007-9175-z
  • Van Huyck, J. B., Gillette, A. B., & Battalio, R. C. (1992). Credible assignments in coordination games. Games and Economic Behavior, 4(4), 606–626. https://doi.org/10.1016/0899-8256(92)90040-Y
  • Van Huyck, J. B., Wildenthal, J. M., & Battalio, R. C. (2002). Tacit cooperation, strategic uncertainty, and coordination failure: Evidence from repeated dominance solvable games. Games and Economic Behavior, 38(1), 156–175. https://doi.org/10.1006/game.2001.0860
  • Weber, E. U., Johnson, E. J., Milch, K. F., Chang, H., Brodscholl, J. C., & Goldstein, D. G. (2007). Asymmetric discounting in intertemporal choice: A query-theory account. Psychological Science, 18(6), 516–523. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9280.2007.01932.x
  • Weber, R., Camerer, C., Rottenstreich, Y., & Knez, M. (2001). The illusion of leadership: Misattribution of cause in coordination games. Organization Science, 12(5), 582–598. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.12.5.582.10090
  • Westbrook, A., Kester, D., & Braver, T. S. (2013). What is the subjective cost of cognitive effort? Load, trait, and aging effects revealed by economic preference. Plos One, 9(7), e68210.
  • White, K., & Lehman, D. R. (2005). Looking on the bright side: Downward counterfactual thinking in response to negative life events. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 31(10), 1413–1424. https://doi.org/10.1177/0146167205276064